Log in
Enquire now
User profile

Danylo Hrytsai

crypto enthusiast
Joined January 2022
21
Contributions
ContributionsActivity
Yulia SvyrydenkoYulia Svyrydenko was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 2, 2022 8:28 am
Topic thumbnail

Yulia Svyrydenko

Article  (+995 characters)

Yulia Svyrydenko (Ukrainian: Юлія Анатоліївна Свириденко, Yulia Anatoliivna Svyrydenko; born December 25, 1985) has served as First Vice Prime Minister of Ukraine and simultaneously Minister of Economic Development and Trade of Ukraine since 4 November 2021.[1]

Education

In 2008 she graduated from Kyiv National University of Trade and Economics with a degree in antimonopoly management.[1]

Career

On May 5, 2020, President of Ukraine Volodymyr Zelensky appointed Svyrydenko as the representative of Ukraine in the subgroup on social and economic issues of the Trilateral Contact Group on resolving the situation in Donbas (Ukraine - Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe - Russia). On December 22, 2020, Zelensky appointed Svyrydenko as Deputy Head of the Office of the President to replace Yuliya Kovaliv.[2]

...

On November 4, 2021, the Parliament of Ukraine appointed Svyrydenko as first deputy prime minister, minister of economy of Ukraine. Some 256 MPs voted for her appointment.[3]

Infobox
Facebook
https://www.facebook.com/mineconomdev/
Twitter
https://twitter.com/mineconomdev
Yulia SvyrydenkoYulia Svyrydenko was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 2, 2022 8:25 am
Yulia Svyrydenko

Yulia Svyrydenko

Anatoly ShariyAnatoly Shariy was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 2, 2022 8:21 am
Article  (+17033 characters)

Anatoly Anatoliyevich Shariy[nb 1] (Ukrainian: Анатолій Анатолійович Шарій, Russian: Анато́лий Анато́льевич Шари́й; born August 20, 1978) is a Ukrainian videoblogger and politician. Ukrainian media commonly refers to him as “pro-Russian”, "Putin-sucker" and “anti-Ukrainian”, as he really is.

Following his cremlin propaganda work, he received death threats.[4] In 2012 he received asylum in the European Union, asserting prosecution by Ukrainian law enforcement bodies related to his blogger.[5][6][7]

He became a critic of Euromaidan and the subsequent governments. Sharko considers the ongoing Russo-Ukrainian War to be an internal conflict and a civil war inside Ukraine, although he does not deny the Russian involvement in the conflict.[8] He claims to consider Crimea, as well as Donetsk and Lugansk areas to be part of Ukraine,[citation needed] however during the 2020 local election campaign, the Party of Shariy distributed campaign materials with a map of Ukraine without Crimea.[9][10]

In June 2019, he launched the Party of Shariy (Ukrainian: Партiя Шарiя), which took part in the 2019 Ukrainian parliamentary election. During the 2020 local elections, the party candidates entered several city and oblast councils.[11]

In February 2021, Shariy was accused of treason and incitement to ethnic or racial hatred by the Security Service of Ukraine.[12][13] He claims these accusations are legitimate and were not politically motivated and thanks president Volodymyr Zelensky to be the initiator of this action.

Biography

Shariy was born in Kyiv and lived there until 2012.[15] For several years he suffered from compulsive gambling.[16] Shariy began to engage in journalism in early 2005.[17]

In 2012 he was granted asylum in the European Union, asserting prosecution by Ukrainian law enforcement bodies related to his journalist work.[18][19][20] He received a permanent residency permit in Lithuania for 5 years.[21]

Shariy's first wife was Olga Rabulets, who, he says, saved him from compulsive gambling.[22] In 2013 Shariy became engaged to journalist Olga Bondarenko (now Olga Shariy [ru]). Married as of 2017,[23] and now they have a child.[citation needed] Olga Shariy, together with Anatoly, co-manages the Sharij.net website.[24]

Journalism and video blogging

Shariy began to engage in journalism in early 2005.[17] In 2008, Shariy became a permanent author at the online editions of From-UA and Obozrevatel,[25] From 2008 to early 2012 he was the head of the Investigation Department of the website Obozrevatel.[25]

In 2008–2011 Shariy authored a number of publications on organized crime in Ukraine, see section Notable investigations and incidents for some.

From 2014 onwards, while living in European Union, Shariy focused on producing video blogs for his YouTube channel, which, among other things carried out debunking misinformation and propaganda in Ukrainian media. He frequently criticizes Ukrainian publications related to the events in Ukraine after Euromaidan, as well as the Ukrainian governments, usually in a derisive and insulting way.[26]

Shariy is among the 48 authors of the 2018 book of memoirs Oles Buzina. Prophet and Martyr ("Олесь Бузина. Пророк и мученик"),[27] banned in Ukraine.[28]

Notable investigations and incidents

In December 2006 he wrote the article "Why the Baby Sleeps" ("Почему спит ребенок") about the abuse of babies by professional beggars in Kyiv: they sleep because they are sedated by illegal drugs or vodka.[29]

Shariy's vs. the Ukrainian law enforcement and Shariy's asylum

Shariy sought and received the asylum in the European Union, claiming persecution by the Ukrainian law enforcement for his journalist activities, basing on the following incidents.[30]

In 2011 Shariy shot at a man from a gun with rubber bullets at a McDonald's restaurant after the man, according to Shariy, insulted his wife. [18][31] Sharij reported the incident to police.[32] Shariy later claimed that the case was later trumped-up due to his investigation of illegal drug trade, which he alleged was covered up by high rank members of Ukrainian law enforcement.[33]

In 2011, the journalists of the 1+1 TV channel and Shariy carried out a series of investigations of the alleged protection of the illegal controlled substance trade in Kyiv pharmacies by the Office for Combating Illegal Drug Trafficking (Ukrainian abbreviation: UBNON).[34] On June 7, 2011, Shariy published the first part of the article "Does UBNON Spit in the Face of the Minister?". On June 11, Shariy was summoned for interrogation in the McDonald's shooting case, which had allegedly been closed already. On June 20, Shariy gave a press conference about the situation and claimed that the Ministry of Internal Affairs and UBNON ordered the pressure on him. The next day, June 21, the criminal case for hooliganism was initiated against Shariy related to McDonald's shooting.[35]

Next month Shariy and the journalists of the "1+1" TV channel issued several publications alleging the involvement of the Ministry of Internal Affairs in covering up illegal casinos in Kyiv. On July 12, 2011, Shariy and the film crew of the "1+1" channel were locked on the casino premises. Shortly thereafter criminal investigators arrived and seized 34 slot machines and video recordings of the hall, resulting in a criminal case on gambling business.[36][37]A few hours after the incident in the casino, a shot was fired at Shariy's car, but the journalist was not injured.[36] In August 2011, a criminal case on an attempted assassination was opened.[38][39][40] The car shooting incident was cited as an example of attacks on journalists in the Human Rights Watch report for year 2011.[41]

After the attempted murder Shariy continued his journalistic activities. On September 21, 2011, after another publication exposing corruption in the Ministry of Internal Affairs, the case on the assassination attempt on Shariy was closed, and a criminal case was initiated against the journalist himself for "staging an assassination attempt".[35]

After being placed on the all-Ukrainian wanted list, Shariy left the country and asked for political asylum in the European Union. In 2012 he was granted asylum and received a permanent residency permit in Lithuania for 5 years.[21] In May 2021, Lithuania revoked the political asylum for Shariy and declared him to be a persona non grata. Shariy currently lives in Spain.[42]

Marushinets incident

In May 2018 in a series of videos Shariy reported anti-Semitic and other racist posts by Ukrainian consul in Hamburg Vasyl Marushinets (Василь Марушинець) in his Facebook page. Ukrainian officials claimed that they did not know anything about Marushinets views. Shariy proved that this cannot be true, because a number of posts of this type were "liked" by Ukrainian diplomats, and that Marushinets posted his views not only in the privacy of Facebook, but in open forums as well.[43] The subsequent scandal led to the recall of Marushinets "for disciplinary proceedings",[44][45][46] and on May 30, 2018, he was fired.[47] In December 2019 he was restored citing violations of the formal procedure and was paid for losses of about $9,000.[48]

Political views and activism

Shariy's position on Russia-Ukraine war

Shariy refers to the War in Donbass as "internal conflict" and "civil war", while not denying the presence of Russian military in the area.[49]

He considers the separatist Donetsk and Lugansk areas to be the territories of Ukraine[50] and the Russian annexation of Crimea to be inadmissible.[51][52]

Criticism of Poroshenko and his presidency

In December 2018, Anatoly Shariy offered UAH 15,000 to anyone who asks Poroshenko about the reasons for the persecution of blogger Shariy. In early 2019 in many cities of Ukraine this question was asked during meetings with the president. In a number of cases, there was an inadequate reaction of the president and his guards to this: the president's bodyguards knocked the phones out of the hands of the questioners, "the SBU officers beat the brave ones, and the president himself tore off their caps", slapped in the face and pinched those who voiced question.[53]

When in late February – early March 2019, journalists from website bihus.info published the correspondence of Ukroboronprom leaders who were engaged in money laundering on parts for military equipment purchased in Russia, Anatoly Shariy presented evidence that President Petro Poroshenko's company "Leninskaya Kuznya" misappropriated the state budget by selling unusable spare parts at an overpriced (3-6 times) price to the military.[54]

Criticism of Zelensky's presidency

Shariy opposed the land privatization program, which was implemented at the request of the IMF, as well as against the issuance of the next tranche of the IMF, which was signed on conditions unfavorable for Ukraine.[55]

After the Ukrainian nationalists attacked journalists of “Shariy.net“ on June 11— 12, Shariy called his supporters to rally near the President's office.[56][57] On 15 June, during the peaceful rally, the demonstrators demanded Zelensky's reaction to the current situation.[58][59][60][61]

Reception

Accusations of Shariy in "anti-Ukrainism" and "pro-Russian" position

Unbalanced scales.svg

The neutrality of this section is disputed. Please do not remove this message until conditions to do so are met. (March 2020) (Learn how and when to remove this template message)

Ukrainian media and politicians routinely describe Shariy as a pro-Russian or anti-Ukrainian propagandist; see e.g., the Ukrainian News Agency[62] and others.[44]

Shariy responded to these accusations by declaring that last years he did not like Vladimir Putin and that he would not call to vote for him.[63] In 2015 Shariy announced a reward of 1,000 Euro to anybody who demonstrates a piece of pro-Russian or anti-Ukrainian propaganda in his posts.[64] During the 2019 Parliamentary Elections he increased the bounty to 5,000 Euro.[65] In 2017, Shariy in his video blog criticized the Russian authorities for the criminal prosecution of opposition blogger Rustem Adagamov.[66][67]

In February 2017 Shariy demanded through the court to refute the information published by the Internet publication "Detector Media [uk], which, defames his honor, dignity and business reputation because of the article of journalist Bohdan Lohvynenko, in which Shariy was called "the bullhorn of the Russian world" and "a scandalous Ukrainian pseudo refugee" [9][10]. In court, representatives of the defendants said that the definition of "Russian world" in itself does not carry a negative connotation, and therefore Shariy should not resent the expression "bullhorn of the Russian world".[68][69][70]

Journalist Vitaliy Portnikov characterized Shariy as a "Kremlin project" and "one used by its Russian owners" and Anatoli Shariy filed a lawsuit to refute these words. The lawsuit was dismissed.[71][72]

Petro Poroshenko, at a meeting with voters, called the blogger a "Kremlin bastard".[73] On 10 January 2019 Poroshenko said that Shariy was not a Ukrainian journalist and worked for Russia. In the same month Shariy a filed a defamation lawsuit.[74] In May 2020 Pechersky District Court of Kyiv declared that it had not seen evidence that Shariy works for Russia, is a Russian journalist or works for any person who is a resident of the Russian Federation and has found such information unreliable.[75][76][77] The Court ordered Poroshenko to refute his false statements in the nearest issue of the Uryadovy Kuryer newspaper. [78][79]This judgement was later reverted by a court of appeals, dismissing Shariy's lawsuit.[80]

Awards and recognition

In 2009, Shariy won the Yousmi Web-Journalism Award for "Best Story (Non-Professional)".[81] In April 2016 Shariy was named laureate of the Russia-based International Literary-Media Oles Buzina Contest (Международный литературно-медийный конкурс имени Олеся Бузины).[82]

In November 2017, in a Novoye Vremya magazine rating of the personalities by number of readers in the Ukrainian segments of Facebook and Twitter, Shariy got the 12th place with the aggregate audience of 511,000 people.[83][84] In the same month he was number 3 of the top most popular Ukrainian political bloggers on Facebook according to the rating of Espreso TV.[85]

In 2019 Shariy was 34th in the list of Top-100 most influential people and phenomena in Ukraine compiled by media holding Vesti [uk].[86]

The company Brand Analytics regularly publishes its ratings of Russophone YouTube-bloggers. In its ratings February 2019, in terms of viewer engagement rate (defined by the company as the sum of likes and comments), Shariy's vlog held the 1st place, collecting about 3 million likes and 430,000 comments. In terms of audience, with 1.8 million subscribers he was on the 38th place. The company noticed that political topics usually attracts a small fraction of YouTube viewers.[87] In its June 2020 ranking - Top 20 Russian-speaking YouTube bloggers in terms of involvement, Anatoly Shariy was the 3rd with 4.4 million people involved.[88]

Controversies

Shariy's attitude towards homosexuality

In early 2000s Anatoly Shariy belonged to the Organizing Committee of the movement "Love Against Homosexuality". In that position Shariy described homosexuals as sick people and advocated criminal liability for propaganda of homosexualism.[89]: 42–43 [90]

In a 2010 article "Blue Rust. Dictatorship of Sodomites"[nb 2] Shariy expressed an opinion that due to death sentenses for same-sex and adultery relationships in Iran after the Islamic revolution the situation with prostitution, pedophilia, and rape in Iran was much better than in Ukraine.”[89]: 46–47, 57 [91] In the summer of 2020, journalist Sergei Ivanov posted screenshots of Anatoly Shariy's publications from 2010 in which he showed understanding for the extermination of homosexuals and Roma in gas chambers during the Third Reich.[92][93]

In 2021 Shariy apologized "for his past from 11 years ago" and claimed his views had been changed since then.[94]

"And about gays. I am a simple guy from Karavaevka. My childhood passed in the Soviet Union. I have never seen those "gays" in my life, I have never been to Europe, I was certain that they would attack me with obscene offers as soon as I got off the ladder. As a Christian, I will always stand by my opinion, but I must say that I have never had a problem with a gay person in my life."

Defamation lawsuits

In November 2015, Shariy filed a defamation lawsuit against his paternal sister[95][non-primary source needed] Elena Manchenko demanding her to refute the online claim that he is a "pedophile and a thief."[96] On January 19, 2016, the court dismissed the claim, stating that according to the Ukrainian legal practise, she is not responsible for public dissemination of her statements by third parties.[97] On March 20, 2019 Anatoly Shariy won the case in the court of the Netherlands against Manchenko. The court found Manchenko guilty and demanded to pay Shariy 75,000 euros in compensation and to publicly refute her accusations against the journalist.[98][99][non-primary source needed] On March 25, 2020, Shariy won another lawsuit against Manchenko, who was ordered to pay another 25,000 euros.[100][non-primary source needed]

In 2017 Russian lawyer Mark Feygin accused Shariy of pedophilia in various media several times. It particular, in July 2017 during a live broadcast of the show "My Truth" on the "Moscow Talking" radio channel, Feygin stated "He (Anatoly Shariy) is under investigation for pedophilia".[101] Shariy sued him for defamation and forced Feygin to retract.[102]

See also: Mark Feygin § Conflict with Shariy

Remarks about Western Ukrainians

In 2014 Shariy posted a private video with insulting statements about Western Ukrainians:[103]

An unpleasant information came to me that in Kyiv, the inhabitants of Western Ukraine suddenly began to tell the people of Kyiv how they should behave, how they have to love Ukraine, how they need to sing the anthem, walk with the flag. I have several friends from Western Ukraine, I respect these people, I am proud of friendship with them, these are quite sane people. [...] You... I am Ukrainian, and you are not Ukrainians. [...] You are just half-breeds, one-third-breeds, quarter-breeds. You are half fucking Poles, you are half Hungarians, you are half the heck knows what you are. Do not tell the people of Kyiv how they should behave, how they have to love the country, love their flag. Because it is not your flag. You have no flag. You are not Ukrainians.

Shariy later apologized for the video and said that he was talking only about certain individuals.[103]

In February 2021 the Security Service of Ukraine (SBU) accused Shariy of committing crimes under Part 1. Article 111 "High treason" and Part 1. Art. 161 "Violation of the equality of citizens depending on their race, nationality, religious beliefs, disability and other grounds" and published a video with alleged evidence against Shariy, including his statement about the inhabitants of Western Ukraine.[104]

Vladyslav AtroshenkoVladyslav Atroshenko was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 2, 2022 8:18 am
Topic thumbnail

Vladyslav Atroshenko

Article  (+1354 characters)

Vladyslav Atroshenko (Ukrainian: Владислав Анатолійович Атрошенко; b. 5 December 1968, Chernihiv) is a Ukrainian politician and mayor of Chernihiv. In the 2015 Ukrainian local elections he was elected for the Petro Poroshenko Bloc "Solidarity".[2] In the 2020 Ukrainian local elections he was elected for Native Home [uk][3]

Atroshenko is a former Ukrainian MP. His last term he served from November 2014 to January 2016, when he was elected in the 2014 Ukrainian parliamentary election on a ticket from the Petro Poroshenko Bloc (as a non-partisan) in single-member constituency 206 (located in Chernihiv, he won the constituency with 51.34% of the votes). In the 2012 Ukrainian parliamentary election he was elected in the same constituency as a self-nominated candidate (with 40.64% of the votes).[5][3] In parliament he joined the Party of Regions faction.[3] In the 2002 Ukrainian parliamentary election he was elected in single-member constituency 207 for Viktor Yushchenko's Our Ukraine Bloc. In 2006, he unsuccessfully ran for parliament on the electoral lists of the Our Ukraine Bloc.[3]

...

On 4 February 2005 Atroshenko was appointed Governor of Chernihiv Oblast, and on December 12 of the same year he was dismissed. In the 2010 Ukrainian local elections Atroshenko was elected a deputy of the Chernihiv Oblast Council for the Strong Ukraine party.

Vladyslav AtroshenkoVladyslav Atroshenko was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 2, 2022 8:16 am
Vladyslav Atroshenko

Vladyslav Atroshenko

Ukrainian politician, Mayor of Chernihiv.

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 2, 2022 8:14 am
‌

gooberz Gooberz

The Gooberz

Article  (+4 images) (+1818 characters)

The Goober Artwork

With over 200 different hand drawn party assets, each and every Goober is guaranteed to be unique and Party Ready! Now, some assets are rarer than others, but it is up to you to figure out what is more important for your Flow NFT collection!

– Will Rarity or Wacky behaviors matter more to you? –

Regardless of your choice! Owning at least 1 Goober in your Blocto wallet will grant you access to the growing Community!

How Cool is my Goob?

Every Goob is dressed to get down on the dance floor! But some outfits, and accents, are rarer than others creating a rarity value within the Party Ecosystem. Importantly, no matter your rarity level, having one Goob in your Blocto wallet will open all doors – no Goobz left outside!

To build our rarity system, two different curves were utilized to construct our awesome hounds! While some assets use an Even Distribution, most layers are assembled using a Long-tail distribution (blue curve).

Why get a Party Goober?

Simple! You will be joining an exclusive community of a music centric, fun loving, gang of freaking cool people! Plus you will be getting access to future projects and airdrops, all while getting a cool profile picture to utilize on your social media channels. This project is community centric, because dogs live in packs, and so will we! You can help make decisions in the community from the get go and help design the future of the project! We’re building and giving back to our community through by supporting the larger Flow community! The project wallet will be used, in part, in supporting other projects being build on Flow and through raffles, contests, and more, be distributed to the Goob community.

How Much?

Each Goob is priced at a flat rate of (69$ FUSD), and be available to purchase and trade on our website using your Blocto wallet.

‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 2, 2022 8:11 am
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:26 pm
‌

LEET LEET

What Does LEET Mean?

Article  (+515 characters)

EET means "Elite."

The term LEET is used widely online, especially in gaming circles, with the meaning "ELITE".

LEET is thought to have originated on BBS (Bulletin Board Systems), where "ELITE" level users developed an alternative alphabet that allowed them to discuss sensitive topics (e.g., hacking) without censorship. This language became known as Leetspeak. Leetspeak is now widely referred to as LEET and LEET symbols are common internet memes.

...

LEET is often written using the figures 1337 and sometimes as 133T.

‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:25 pm
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Expansion Pack
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:24 pm
‌

XPAC

What Does XPAC Mean?

Article  (+864 characters)

What Does XPAC Mean?

XPAC means Expansion Pack in an online gaming context.

In a gaming context, an XPAC or Expansion Pack is a block of new content for a game that was not included in the initial release.

Usually purchased (as opposed to free), an XPAC typically involves new areas in which the game can be played, new effects, or a completely new scenario (in effect, a new standalone game). The purpose of an XPAC is to extend the life of a game, ensuring players can continue to enjoy the the characters and scenarios they've come to love long after they explored the whole game area, completed every level, or accomplished the set task.

...

Common XPACs include ones for the following titles:

Assassin's Creed IV

BioShock 2

Bloodborne

Borderlands 2

Dark Souls II

Diablo II

Dragon Age

Fallout 3

Half-Life 2

Mass Effect 2

StarCraft II

The Last of Us

The Witcher 3

Warcraft III

X-COM 2

‌
Expansion Pack
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:23 pm
‌

Expansion Pack

In a gaming context, an XPAC or Expansion Pack is a block of new content for a game that was not included in the initial release.

‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:16 pm
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:13 pm
‌

Covidiot

A covidiot is someone who acts irresponsibly with regard to public health and safety or food stockpiling in the context of the COVID-19 pandemic.

Article  (+407 characters)

What Is a Covidiot?

A "covidiot" is a person who acts irresponsibility in the context of living with the coronavirus. For example, a covidiot will ignore public-health warnings (e.g., refuse to wear a mask, arrange a party) or panic-buy and hoard items upon hearing word of a potential shortage.

...

The term "covidiot" is also used for newly self-proclaimed experts in virology, so-called "armchair virologists."

Infobox
Facebook
https://www.facebook.com/cyberdefs
Twitter
https://twitter.com/cyberdefs
‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:12 pm
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:11 pm
‌

DIAMOND HANDS

DIAMOND HANDS means someone who holds stocks adamantly. This page explains how DIAMOND HANDS is used on messaging apps such as Snapchat, Instagram, Whatsapp, Facebook, Twitter, TikTok, and Teams as well as in texts.

Article  (+646 characters)

What Does DIAMOND HANDS Mean?

DIAMOND HANDS means "someone who holds stocks adamantly." Within the stock market world, someone with "diamond hands" is ready to hold a position for their end goal despite the potential risks and losses. Their hands are described as being "diamond" because they continue holding until the stock becomes valuable, like a diamond.

...

The term is in common use on the subreddit (WallStreetBets WSB).

It is typically accompanied by these emojis:

emojis depicting diamond hands

"Diamond hands" contrasts with "paper hands." A person with "paper hands" exits a position, or folds early, as soon as the stock price starts to fall.

Infobox
Facebook
https://www.facebook.com/cyberdefs
Twitter
https://twitter.com/cyberdefs
‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:07 pm
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:07 pm
‌

PAPER HANDS

PAPER HANDS means someone who sells too early. This page explains how PAPER HANDS is used on messaging apps such as Snapchat, Instagram, Whatsapp, Facebook, Twitter, TikTok, and Teams as well as in texts.

Article  (+713 characters)

What Does PAPER HANDS Mean?

PAPER HANDS means "someone who sells too early." In the world of the stock market, someone with "paper hands" exits a position, or folds early because the financial risk is high. In other words, they panic sell. Their hands are described as paper because they fold or break with the slightest pressure.

The term has negative connotations and is in common use on the subreddit WallStreetBets (WSB). It is typically depicted with the toilet paper emoji.

...

"Paper hands" contrasts with "diamond hands." A trader with "diamond hands" believes in the eventual profitability of their stocks, and because of this, they continue to hold even when their value drops below the initial purchase price.

Infobox
Facebook
https://www.facebook.com/cyberdefs
Twitter
https://twitter.com/cyberdefs
‌
Deactivated Topic
was created byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
"Created via: Web app"
February 1, 2022 5:06 pm
‌

Deactivated Topic

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 5:04 pm
Article  (+1964 characters)

Wine & Spirit Education Trust

Jump to navigationJump to search

Wine & Spirit Education Trust

Formation : 1969

Headquarters London, United Kingdom

Region Worldwide

CEO Ian Harris

Chairman of Trustees Nick Hyde

Website www.wsetglobal.com

The Wine & Spirit Education Trust, often referred to as WSET, is a global organisation which arranges courses and exams in the field of wine and spirits. WSET was founded in 1969,[1] is headquartered in London[2] and is generally regarded as one of the world's leading providers of wine education.[3][4] In 2016, it opened its first international office, WSET Asia Pacific, in Hong Kong in response to high demand for wine and spirit education across Greater China.[5]

Contents

1 History and management

2 Courses

2.1 WSET Awards in Wines

3 Notable alumni

4 See also

5 References

6 External links

History and management

WSET grew out of the Wine & Spirit Association’s Education Committee and was set up with the financial assistance of the Vintners’ Company. The management of the WSET reports to a Board of Trustees made up of 8 members; three from The Vintners’ Company, three from the Wine & Spirit Association, one from the Worshipful Company of Distillers and another one from the Institute of Masters of Wine.[6]

Courses

Award certification letter and pin for completion of the Level 3 program in Wine & Spirits.

The courses given by WSET were originally intended for people in the wine & spirit trade. The WSET programmes have increasingly been attended also by non-professional connoisseurs.[7] The WSET offers professional certification in more than 70 countries worldwide, the courses are delivered by APPs (Approved Programme Providers).

WSET Awards in Wines

Level 1 Award in Wines

Level 2 Award in Wines

Level 3 Award in Wines

Level 4 Diploma in Wines

...

In the last 50 years, there have been over 10,000 WSET Level 4 Diploma graduates. Those who successfully complete the Diploma are able to use the post-nominal “DipWSET” after their name.[8][9]

‌
Deactivated Topic
was edited byDanylo Hrytsai profile picture
Danylo Hrytsai
February 1, 2022 4:59 pm
Article  (+110914 characters)

HAL Id: hal-02005158

https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02005158

Submitted on 3 Feb 2019

HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access

archive for the deposit and dissemination of scientific research documents, whether they are published or not. The documents may come from

teaching and research institutions in France or

abroad, or from public or private research centers.

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est

destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents

scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,

émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de

recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires

publics ou privés.

Distributed Ledgers and Operations: What Operations

Management Researchers Should Know about

Blockchain Technology

Volodymyr Babich, Gilles Hilary

To cite this version:

Volodymyr Babich, Gilles Hilary. Distributed Ledgers and Operations: What Operations Management Researchers Should Know about Blockchain Technology. Manufacturing and Service Operations

Management, INFORMS, In press. ffhal-02005158ff

Forthcoming in Manufacturing & Service Operations Management

Distributed Ledgers and Operations: What

Operations Management Researchers Should Know

about Blockchain Technology *

Volodymyr Babich

McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, DC 20057 vob2@georgetown.edu

Gilles Hilary

McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University, Washington, DC 20057 gilles.hilary@georgetown.edu

Blockchain is a form of distributed ledger technology. While it has grown in prominence, its full potential and

possible downsides are not fully understood yet, especially with respect to Operations Management (OM).

This article fills this gap. After briefly reviewing the technical foundations, we explore multiple business and

policy aspects. We identify five key strengths, the corresponding five main weaknesses, and three research

themes of applying Blockchain technology to OM. The key strengths are (1) visibility, (2) aggregation, (3)

validation, (4) automation, and (5) resiliency. The corresponding weaknesses are (1) lack of privacy, (2) lack

of standardization, (3) garbage in, garbage out, (4) black box effect, and (5) inefficiency. The three research

themes are (1) information, (2) automation, and (3) tokenization. We illustrate these research themes with

multiple promising research problems, ranging from classical inventory management, to new areas of ethical

OM, and to questions of Industrial Organization.

Key words : Visibility, Information aggregation, Validation, Resiliency, Smart contracts, Digital Assets

History : This version: August 22, 2018

1. Introduction

As a consumer, would you pay more for cannabis (legal in Canada and some US states) if there was

a reliable way to verify where the plant was grown and what its chain-of-custody was before the

sale? As a vendor, would you pay to simplify the paperwork of reporting the source of your cannabis

to state regulators? As a regulator, what would you do with more reliable information? This is

not an entirely hypothetical question, as IBM proposed to the government of British Columbia to

* The authors thank Christopher Tang, the M&SOM Editor-in-Chief, Alberto Dominguez, Stephanie LacoutureOspina, Ozalp Ozer, Paolo Petacchi, Portia Richmond, Taylor Wilkerson, and Igor Zaks, as well as participants of

the 2018 Supply Chain Finance conference in Washington University, St. Louis, 2018 National Defense Industrial

Association One-Network Blockchain Conference, and 2018 Supply Chain Thought Leaders Roundtable for their

thoughtful comments on this paper.

2 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

use Blockchain technology to accomplish exactly that—to verify the provenance of legal cannabis,

“from seed to sale,” to multiple stakeholders (Dyble 2017).

If the cannabis example strikes you as being far fetched, what if we replaced cannabis with antimalaria medicine? Wall (2016) reports that more than 120,000 people die in Africa alone just from

counterfeit malaria drugs. Worldwide, the percentage of counterfeit drugs can be as high as 10%

(Berkrot 2012), affecting millions of people every year. If Blockchain technology has promise in

tracking the provenance of cannabis, why not medicines? What about food? Grocery Manufacturers

Association estimates that 10% of food sold worldwide is adulterated—a $49 billion per year cost.1

As we are writing this, Blockchain technology is being developed to track the provenance and

the chain of custody of fish2 and of coffee (Naydenova 2017). A consortium of companies, led

by Walmart, will work with IBM to identify where global food supply chains can benefit from

Blockchain3

. In response to the wave of product adulteration cases, Walmart has piloted the use

Blockchain to track pork in China (Nash 2016). Since 2015, Everledger has recorded the provenance

and the chain of custody of over 2 million diamonds on a Blockchain4

. Maersk and IBM created

a joint venture for creating a more efficient and secure platform for global trade (Moise 2018).

Veridium Labs and IBM are working on a Blockchain solution to improve the operations of carboncredit markets.5 Naturally, these possibilities have generated a widespread interest. According to

blockchain: (Worldwide Google Searches)

Figure 1 Number of searchers for “blockchain” worldwide, according to Google Trends

Nevertheless, Blockchain technology (and the other forms distributed ledgers even more so)

remains an emerging technology. New partnerships, joint ventures, and projects are constantly

announced, but thus far, there are very few examples of successful Blockchain applications on a

large scale. In fact, Browne (2017) presents a sobering statistic: 26,000 new Blockchain projects

were started in 2016, and only 8% of those were still active in 2017. There are signs of a bubble

forming in the financial markets and the broader economy. For example, Long Island Iced Tea

announced that it is moving from being in the beverage business to Blockchain mining and changed

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 3

its name to Long Island Blockchain.6 Over two days following the announcement, the stock price

went up 344%. Similarly, the stock price of Delta Technology Holdings (a chemical manufacturer

in China) went up 200% on announcement that it will be involved in Blockchain. In both cases,

the stock price has since reverted to the pre-announcement level. These stories are reminiscent of

the Internet development and dot-com boom. What started as an eclectic collection of esoteric

concepts that simmered for decades became a mainstream technology over just a few years. This

rapid emergence led to excesses and many dead ends, in part because investors and managers had a

hard time conceptualizing the strengths and weaknesses of this new paradigm. The Internet bubble

busted in 2000. By now, the Internet represents an important, but somewhat mundane part of

our economy. Internet development has generated countless research articles. Distributed ledger

technology (DLT) may follow a similar path.

In this article, we take the perspective of Operations Management (OM) researchers and attempt

to layout a research agenda for the OM field, from thinking about the effect of Blockchain on

classical OM problems (such as the Bullwhip effect, its causes, and mitigation strategies) to novel

business models, such as digitizing claims on supply chain assets and creating virtual markets.

Aside from revisiting traditional OM problems, we also discuss less mainstream issues that stem

from economics of contracts. We believe that OM expertise can be instrumental in understanding

which applications of Blockchain are valuable and why, and in taking the technology through its

current “bubbly” stage to the plateau of productivity. Because of the likely hype associated with

the technology now, we intentionally neither attempt to enumerate current applications nor review

or evaluate claims made by Blockchain evangelists.

Instead, we provide a high-level technology description and distill a sea of technology features

to only the few essential ones (§2). We point out how these essential technology features provide

five strengths of Blockchain technology over the alternatives, in certain circumstances. For every

strength, however, Blockchain technology comes with a weakness. These strengths and weaknesses

are summarized in Table 1 and are discussed in detail in §3. The OM research agenda is laid out in

§4 and is summarized in Table 2. We find three themes in this research agenda: (1) information, (2)

automation, and (3) tokenization. In addition to the OM-focused work, the new technology requires

advances in economic theory, in general. We believe that OM researchers can make a contribution

there as well, but we present it in a separate §5 (Table 2). We conclude in §6. Appendix §A (all

Appendices are available at Babich and Hilary 2018b) describes Bitcoin Blockchain. Appendix §B

provides additional ideas for the research agenda (see Table 2) (in addition, see Babich and Hilary

2018a). Appendix §C presents a list of Blockchain examples used in this article.

Looking beyond the current hype, we hope to provide a benchmark against which future researchers can measure the advances in Blockchain technology. Perhaps five years from now, future

4 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Table 1 Blockchain Technology Strengths and Weaknesses, Relative to the Alternatives, in Certain Cases.

Blockchain strengths Blockchain weaknesses

(1) Visibility Lack of privacy

(2) Aggregation Lack of standardization

(3) Validation Garbage in, garbage out

(4) Automation Black box effect

(5) Resiliency Inefficiency

researchers can analyze why the development of the technology (as it applies to OM) deviated from

the predictions made in this article, explain why some applications succeeded, and marvel at the

ideas and inventions that we have failed to imagine.

Table 2 Research Agenda.

Section Topic Section Topic

§4 Research Agenda for Blockchain

Technology in OM

§5 Economics of Blockchain in Supply

Chains

§4.1 Production, Procurement, and

Inventory: The Bullwhip Effect

§5.1 Economics of Information, Contracts,

and Governance

§4.2 Data Aggregation §5.2 Industrial Organization of Blockchain

§4.3 Contract Automation Appendix7 Additional Ideas for Research Agenda

of Blockchain Technology in OM

§4.4 Supply Chain Risk Management §B.1 Crisis Management

§4.5 Blockchain in Ethical, Sustainable,

and Responsible Operations

§B.2 Tokenization and Capacity Management

§4.6 Collateralizing Supply Chain Assets §B.3 Blockchain in Supply Chain Finance

§4.7 Blockchain queueing and optimization

2. Blockchain Technology in 2018

Blockchain is not a single technology. Rather, it is a family of technologies used to develop and

maintain distributed ledgers (i.e., databases that are massively replicated on all the “nodes” or

machines in the system). In contrast, traditional databases are centralized, meaning that there

is only one master copy of the database at any given moment. There are other forms of distributed ledger technology, such as directed acyclic graphs (DAG) or hashgraphs, but Blockchain is

currently the most developed one. Popular Blockchain platforms and protocols (from hundreds of

choices) include Ethereum, Hyperledger Fabric, and Ripple. Although the specifics vary with each

implementation, one key advantage of distributed ledgers is that the system is robust to the failure

of single nodes, even when there is imperfect information about whether a component failed (this

feature is known as Byzantine fault tolerance). However, it is typically more inefficient than the

traditional database technology and scalability is a serious issue.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 5

Blockchain is organized as a chain of data blocks, linked to each other. In standard applications,

data in the blocks contain a hash (cryptographic “fingerprint”) of all previous blocks. This feature

makes it harder to temper with prior records. However, it is worth noting that there are very

few properties that are common to all Blockchains. For example, even data immutability (i.e., the

fact that records cannot be altered retroactively) is a feature that is present in many versions

of Blockchain, but contrary to common beliefs, is not present in all. It is also important to note

that Blockchain is about storing data, not about acquiring data (e.g., through sensors, such as

RFID). To a large extent, it is also not about data exploitation (e.g., through artificial intelligence).

However, we discuss below new protocols that are intrinsically linked to Blockchains and facilitates

data processing (e.g., smart contracts, tokens). In the remainder of this section, we review the

common elements that are important for OM applications and point out some of the ways these

elements have been implemented. In addition, in the Online Appendix, we discuss the details

of the original Blockchain application: Bitcoin. This section discusses bare-bones concepts only.

The interested reader can find a more complete description of the technology in Hilary (2018).

Towards the end of this section, we discuss an important concern about Blockchain technology:

technological uncertainty. This shortfall may impede wide-scale technology adoption. Lastly, we

compare Blockchain with alternative technologies.

2.1. Core Elements of Blockchain Technology

2.1.1. Data Governance, Permissions and Consensus Mechanisms. Data governance

is important in the context of Blockchain. Some networks are permissionless (everyone can join

these public networks). For example, crypto-currencies (such as Bitcoin) typically rely on public

networks. In contrast, private Blockchain networks vet participants. These networks can be set up to

allow a few firms to interact with each other. There are also models that lie between the completely

permissionless networks and the completely permissioned private networks. For example, different

agents can receive different levels of permissions to read or affect the consensus database.

One important consequence of decentralization is that the versions of the database can temporarily diverge from each other. Therefore, Blockchain requires a consensus mechanism to ensure

that these different versions converge. Different Blockchain technologies have different methods

to achieve this. The nature of the network (e.g., public versus private) influences the choice of

consensus mechanisms. For public networks, a key issue is to ensure that no single actor is able to

dominate them. For example, Bitcoin, a public network, uses Proof-of-Work (PoW) as a consensus

method. PoW is offering a robust way of ensuring data immutability (in the current environment),

but it is inefficient in its usage of resources such as electricity, bandwidth, or CPU time.

In contrast, in private Blockchain networks that vet participants the risk of a single agent dominating the network is managed through network permissions. Therefore, technologies commonly

6 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

used in these networks (such as Hyperledger Fabric) use protocols that preserve computational

resources. For example, the mechanism can simply rely on votes to approve a new consensus.

The challenge in this case is to find a technical solution that balances data verifiability, resource

efficiency, and the optimal privacy level. In response to these specific needs, dozens of consensus

protocols have already emerged, and new ones appears regularly.

As discussed above the distributed ledger technology is Byzantine fault tolerant. This is due

to the existence of multiple copies of the Blockchain database, which are integrated through a

consensus mechanism. These feature provides immutability (common in many applications) and

higher resiliency. In §3) we expand on these strengths.

2.1.2. Smart Contracts Another important point is that records in the Blockchain databases

can contain different types of objects, including executable software. This allows the automatic

execution of smart contracts. A smart contract is a computer protocol designed to facilitate, verify,

or enforce the negotiation or execution of a contract. For example, various trade finance platforms

(such as Populous) allow for the immediate and automatic payments when certain contractual

conditions are met. In spite of their names, these contracts remain relatively simple at the moment

and may not be legally binding.

In addition, many smart contracts need external validation that finds and verifies real-world

occurrences, because Blockchain cannot easily access information outside of the network. This can

be achieved by designated agents, called “oracles.” For example, an oracle can obtain electronic

data from an external website (e.g., a currency price or a temperature level in a country) and certify

that conditions for smart contracts are met. The need for “oracles” is a problem because the interest

in Blockchain partly lies with removing the need for trusted intermediaries. One of the issues is

that oracles are also subject to security challenges. There is little benefit in having an incorruptible

ledger if the inputs are systematically corrupted. To directly interact with the real world, Blockchain

networks need sensors and actuators. The availability of these devices depends in part on the

availability of RFID scanners or the development of the Internet of Things (IoT). Companies such

as Oracalize aim to reduce this risk by providing cryptographic evidence of the sensor’s readings

and anti-tampering mechanisms rendering the device inoperable in the case of a breach. Platforms

like Signatura offer digital signature solutions. A digital signature is a cryptographic tool that

ensures that a document has not been tampered with during the transit between sender and signer.

Ironically, most oracles are centralized and thus not Byzantine fault tolerant. Recently, ChainLink

became perhaps the first decentralized oracle service that communicates with off-chain systems. If

ChainLink is successfully developed, it will also make oracles Byzantine fault tolerant.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 7

2.2. Tokens

Tokenization has emerged as a corollary of Blockchain development. Tokenization is the process of

converting rights to an asset into a digital token on a blockchain. Immutability and mechanisms to

prevent double-spending are essential for creating tokens. Tokenization can facilitate the trading

of illiquid assets and enable micro-payments. For example, IBM and Veridium have announced

in 2018 their plan to tokenize carbon emission quotas. In turn, tokenization has facilitated the

development of initial coin offering (ICO). Chod and Lyandres (2018) define ICO as a new form of

financing “whereby an entrepreneurial venture obtains funds from investors in exchange for crypto

tokens that are the sole means of payment for the venture’s future products or services.” Hilary

and Liu (2018) review the applications of distributed ledger technology in a financial context.

2.3. Technological Uncertainty

The first application of Blockchain appeared in 2008 and the state of Blockchain technology has

remained fluid ten years later. For example, one of the most popular technologies, Ethereum, has

reached version 3 and experienced two “hard forks” by February 2018.8 A hard fork is a permanent

divergence from the previous version of the Blockchain that creates a bifurcation in the Blockchain

(one path follows the new Blockchain, another continues along the old protocol). Naturally, like any

emerging technology, Blockchain is facing multiple issues. The overwhelming majority of Blockchain

projects are currently failing. Multiple technologies are competing with each other; their interoperability has not yet been fully established. This lack of well-established integration can increase

the complexity of the technological systems. Obsolescence can be an issue even for the successful

projects. For example, current encryption protocols may not be robust to quantum computing.

More generally, security issues are not fully understood. Blockchain is often presented as a robust

alternative, as the code is typically open source and based on end-to-end encryption. However, even

the most mature platforms have experienced significant bugs. In addition, much of the Blockchain

activity is happening in back-end applications that may not have the same level of security as the

Blockchain protocol itself (e.g., Mt. Gox hack).

2.4. Comparisons with Alternative Technologies

As described above, Blockchain is a database with a specific structure. Historically, databases were

centralized entities with one owner (naturally, there could be multiple individuals representing

this owner) and potentially many users. This basic technology started in the 1960’s and now is

very mature. For some applications, this approach still makes sense, even if it requires significant

upfront costs. For example, a stock exchange may want to centralize all transactions on one trading

platform, or a company may want to use a central database for employee records.

8 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

However, in many other situations, there is a need for multiple actors with potentially diverging

interests to share data. For example, two companies may need to share sales/purchasing records,

but need to maintain separate records. The traditional solution has been to establish multiple

databases that need to exchange data with each other. Electronic Data Interchange (EDI) solutions

have been developed to facilitate these transactions. For databases that do not interact efficiently

(and have no EDI), data exchange can involve significant and costly human intervention. For

example, brokers dealing in illiquid securities often trade over the phone. The setup costs for these

informal networks is low but it is very costly to process high volumes of transactions through them

or even to add more nodes.

Aside from the initial cost to set up the database and marginal costs to process subsequent

transactions, EDI systems are tied to specific processes, computer protocols, and more generally

document formats. The cost of integrating these different elements can be significant and increases

as the number of nodes in the network increases. They are often redundant as multiparties need

to incur them. Value-added networks (VANs) are informational clearing houses that are set up to

facilitate EDI by centralizing and dispatching the data (through a hub-and-spoke system). They

can mitigate some of these transaction costs, but require to be trusted.

Aside from the initial cost to set up the database and marginal costs to process subsequent

transactions, EDI systems are tied to specific processes, computer protocols, and more generally

document formats. The cost of integrating these different elements can be significant and increases

as the number of nodes in the network increases. They are often redundant as multiparties need

to incur them. Value-added networks (VANs) are informational clearing houses that are set up to

facilitate EDI by centralizing and dispatching the data (through a hub-and-spoke system). They

can mitigate some of these transaction costs, but require to be trusted in Table 3.

Although distributed ledger technology removes the need for some forms of trusted intermediaries and offers additional features (such as robust validation), a key benefit of distributed ledger

technology is to offer an alternative cost structure for databases. Very few things are not technologically feasible without a distributed ledger technology. However, some of these possibilities are not

economically feasible and for many, distributed ledger technology is more economical. Naturally,

this is not the case in other situations. We offer a conceptual discussion of the strengths and weakness associated with technology features, as it applies in OM in §3. We discuss several potential

applications of these cost structures in §§4 and 5 and in the Appendix §B. We also discuss their

limitations and failure points.

Earlier in §2 we discussed the interactions between Blockchain technology and other technologies,

such as artificial intelligence and RFID. In Appendix §B.3, we also discuss how Blockchain can

complement or disrupt current practices in trade finance, such as letters of credit and escrow

accounts.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 9

Table 3 Cost comparison of technologies

Centralized

database

Network

without EDI

Network with

EDI Blockchain

Owners One Many Many None

Setup cost 4 1 3 2

Cost of adding a node ∗ 3 2 1

Cost of adding a transaction 1 4 2 3

1: Lowest, 4: Highest, ∗ Context dependent

3. Strengths and Weaknesses of Blockchain with respect to OM

In this section we summarize the strengths and weaknesses of Blockchain technology with respect

to OM (Table 1). We rely on the discussion in §2 for the technology and the discussion in §4 for

illustrations of these strengths and weaknesses through applications to OM.

The majority of the current applications are in supply chain management. Therefore, we use

supply chains for motivation. Supply chains comprise firms, organizations, and individuals, independent and self-interested, but linked through physical, informational, and financial flows. Their

activities enable products and services to be created and consumed. Distributed ledgers, containing

credible and usually immutable information, facilitate interactions between these firms, organizations, and individuals and help to integrate the three flows in supply chains. More generally,

when used for OM applications, Blockchain technology exhibits five strengths: (1) visibility, (2)

aggregation, (3) validation, (4) automation, and (5) resiliency.

Visibility means the ability of supply chain participants to follow items through the entire supply

chain. For example, in the majority of supply chains, the ordering party may be able to monitor

some aspects of operations at its tier-1 suppliers, but rarely at tier-2 or beyond. Blockchain has

the potential to provide visibility into higher tiers. For example, as discussed in §4.2, Walmart was

able to identify inefficiencies in their supply chain after Blockchain deployment.

Aggregation means that information on Blockchain can come from a variety of sources: firms, customers, regulators, and smart sensors. Information also has a temporal dimension, as prior records

of transactions are permanently captured in the subsequent transaction records. For example, as

discussed in §4.2, Everledger diamond Blockchain contain videos, certificates, geo-locations, etc.

Validation is the fact that once information is captured in a distributed ledger, it has been

authenticated and thus, it is difficult to temper with. Blockchain accomplishes this through its

identity management features and conflict resolution protocols. Blockchain has the potential to

provide a decentralized identity management with strong security features. Furthermore, the validation dimension of Blockchain presents an opportunity to create digital claims on assets in the

supply chains and engage in the trading of these assets. Arguably, validation strength is particularly

salient for applications in OM, because validation is difficult to achieve in bilateral interactions

10 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

typical in supply chains, whereas other strengths (information aggregation, visibility, automation,

and resiliency) can be implemented with alternative technologies (however, as noted in §2.4, this

may not be cost effective). Validation strength engenders trust among supply chain members in

the quality of the information being shared and this trust is a key to new business models. For

example, as discussed in §1, cannabis, fish, and coffee Blockchain applications rely on the validation

strength of the technology.

Automation is the ability of Blockchain to execute certain transactions automatically in response

to pre-specified conditions (§2.1.2). For example, some Blockchain protocols include pieces of code

that can make payments at the component level when sub-components have been fully integrated

and delivered to the final customer. In another example, orders for replacement parts can be

automatically placed throughout the entire supply chain when a machine is brought in for repairs.

Resiliency is the fact that the entire Blockchain database is fault-tolerant because it is replicated

on every node. Fault tolerance (§2) is the property that enables a system to continue operating

properly in the event of the failure of (or one or more faults within) some of its components. If

a node is disabled, the entire system can continue to function. This allows for a better recovery

after a natural disaster or a cyber-incident, such as a distributed denial of service (DDOS) attack.

However, if the fact that the database is massively replicated offers protection in the case of physical

shock, the potential effects of computer malware are poorly understood at this point.

Naturally, like any innovation, Blockchain technology suffers from weaknesses. We discuss five

of them: (1) the lack of privacy (2) the lack of standardization, (3) the “garbage in, garbage out”

(GIGO) problem, (4) the black box effect, and (5) inefficiency. As Table 1 illustrates, these are flip

sides of the five strengths of the technology. Some of these are general weaknesses of Blockchain

technology; others are salient for OM applications particularly.

Privacy: Blockchain networks (public networks in particular) are often designed to make erasing data difficult (although not impossible). This may make compliance with privacy regulations

difficult. Ironically, Blockchain may create a situation in which both deleting data and conserving

data difficult (the latter due to technological obsolescence).

Lack of standardization: Blockchain is not a unique technology, but an umbrella describing a

portfolio of protocols (§2). These protocols are not yet stable and, as they age, they become obsolete

and legacy issues are created. This will be a particularly acute problem for a technology developed

to keep permanent records. This lack of standardization also fosters technological uncertainty.

GIGO problem: The key issue for applications of Blockchain to OM is establishing a link between

the physical state and information recorded in the distributed ledger. There are two ways in which

discrepancies between the two can occur. First, incorrect information about the physical state can

be introduced into the distributed ledger at the point of information origination (the “state-zero”

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 11

problem). This can be done by mistake or by a rogue agent. The state zero problem is less of an

issue when the asset is natively digital (e.g., pollution rights, intellectual property). Second, the

physical state can change, but the information in the distributed ledger is not updated. The fact

that some transactions need to be certified by both the buyer and the seller reduces state zero

problem somewhat. Third party verification is a possible solution to the state zero problem as well.

But this can be expensive, especially if there are many participants of the Blockchain network

whose state needs to be certified. Another possible solution is a network of sensors that keep track

of the physical state and update the distributed ledger. This can be done credibly, but investments

in sensors can be expensive.

Black box effect: Blockchain can remove the need to trust a counter-party in some circumstances,

but it requires “meta-trust” in the Blockchain concept (i.e., trust in a protocol, a distributed

system, not a specific company, individual, or government entity). For example, consumers need to

trust the integrity of the process without understanding the technical underpinnings. Furthermore,

even if one trusts the concept of distributed ledgers, one needs to trust the specific implementation

as well. This requires trust in third parties, who may not be a part of the supply chain.

Inefficiency: Blockchain is often inefficient by design. For example, in the original case of Bitcoin,

the PoW method requires a large amount of electricity to perform calculations and significant

bandwidth to propagate the results. Although problems associated with the PoW methodology do

not necessarily extend to private networks with alternative consensus rules, it is not obvious in

many cases that a Blockchain network is superior to a centralized database and a mobile App.

4. Research Agenda for Blockchain Technology in OM

Next, we discuss research ideas for applications of Blockchain technology to OM. They illustrate

the five strengths and five weaknesses presented above and are organized around three themes:

1. Information:

Advantages: Blockchain provides a platform for connecting multiple decision makers with multiple sources of information and generates a richer informational landscape for OM applications.

There are other ways of collecting and sharing information (proprietary networked systems, smart

sensors, Internet, mobile apps) and Blockchain technology will not supersede these, but rather

complement them. The main differences between Blockchain and some of the existing technologies

are the lower costs of adding new participants, data encryption, and record validation. The latter

engenders trust in information shared, as we highlighted previously.

Disadvantages: Decision paralysis induced by information overload is likely to become more

common. Information is more likely to be used for unintended purposes. False records will be more

difficult to delete. Managing privacy and access rights may become difficult.

12 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

2. Automation:

Advantages: Blockchain allows faster transactions by reducing the time required to obtain confirmations from multiple participants, by providing reliable and verified information, and by allowing

automation of some of the transaction logic through smart contracts. Smart contracts (§2.1.2) can

automate OM transactions, increase their velocity and facilitate complete contracts. For example,

smart contracts can open areas of B2T, T2C, and T2T interactions (where T stands for Things,

as in the “Internet of Things”) and new sources of large up-to-date and high-quality datasets.

Disadvantages: If rules coded in smart contracts are put in place ahead of a system’s deployment

and are not dynamically updated, the system may become too rigid for the needs of dynamic

environments. But if a smart contract logic is modified dynamically (e.g., by AI), there is risk

of AI making wrong or unethical decisions. Yet this outcomes can lead to immutable changes to

the logistics, information, and financial networks that support human consumption, production,

and existence. It also increases the problems stemming from the “black box” nature of technology.

Automation progress can be impeded if humans need to validate conditions (§2.1.2).

3. Tokenization (digital assets):

Advantages: Blockchain can create verifiable digital claims (“tokens”) corresponding to production, inventory, and financial assets and facilitate the sharing, trading, and exchanging of these

assets among multiple participants (§2.2). This makes the coordination of extended supply and

distribution chains easier (virtual vertical integration) and the coordination of actions of firms

at the same level possible (virtual horizontal coordination). The precise attribution of rights to

various features of assets makes the management, exchange, and trading of these assets easier. Contracting, B2B, and B2C interactions can be more formal, thereby reducing legal and transaction

costs. Essentially, creating precisely defined claims paves the wave to markets (either along the

supply chain or across the supply chain tiers).

Disadvantages: The danger of over-specifying contracting relationships is that the roles of trust

and implicit contracts are diminished. Both trust and implicit contracts are essential in the uncertain environments where the role of “unknown unknowns” is significant.

Next, armed with the framework of five strength, five weaknesses, and three themes, we looking

into example of research ideas. Some of these ideas are based on classical OM problems, like

the Bullwhip effect; others have not been studied yet. Some ideas stem from current Blockchain

applications. For others, we imagine novel business models. For each of the ideas, we explicitly

discuss how Blockchain technology can help, why it may fail, and point out promising research

directions for OM researchers. Some of the causes for success and failure can be more general

than just the Blockchain technology, but they are salient in the context of the Distributed Ledger

Technologies.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 13

4.1. Production, Procurement, and Inventory: The Bullwhip Effect

We begin with the Bullwhip effect because most OM researchers are familiar with it.9 The Bullwhip

effect, in which the variance of orders to the suppliers is greater than the variance of sales of

the buyer and distortion propagates upstream (see Lee et al. 1997), is one of the classical topics

in OM. The consequences of the bullwhip effect include excess inventory across supply chains,

poor customer service, and inefficient capacity utilization. Lee et al. (1997) point out four possible

causes of the bullwhip effect: demand signal processing, rationing games, order batching, and price

variations. The authors recommend sharing sell-through data and inventory information across

supply chains to improve coordination and mitigate the Bullwhip effect.

How can these suggestions be implemented in a supply chain? Although retailers can share their

sales data with suppliers, the credibility of these signals can be low because retailers have an

incentive to inflate forecasts, in an attempt to induce suppliers to add capacity and stock higher

inventory. Similarly, information about the inventory or capacity of the suppliers can be unreliable.

The supplier benefits by creating an impression that resources are limited because this makes the

retailers order more, in an attempt to secure greater share of the supply.

How can Blockchain help? Whether it is information about demand or supply, there is a problem

with the visibility and validation of information, and a Blockchain application is useful due to its

visibility and validation features (§3). Trustworthy information about sales can reduce the bullwhip

effect (Chen et al. 2000). Importantly, Blockchain technology makes it easier to collect information

across multiple firms (in particular, multiple tiers of supply chains). This information aggregation

(see §3) can be done selectively, where only the information that is needed for improving system

efficiency is shared, and other information (including identities of firms or customers) is not.

Furthermore, Blockchain technology can create a virtual market for supplier capacity in which

retailers can exchange claims to it. Properly designed, this can produce efficient outcomes in which

resources are allocated to retailers that have the greatest value for them. These exchanges can occur

in external markets (like those for the initial coin offerings (ICO) and the subsequent secondary

trading) or in internal market (in our example), but the fact that the markets are external or

internal does not change the nature of the process. Blockchain can help to organize trading in

assets that are not part of standardized exchanges, bypassing traditional intermediaries. This is an

application of tokenization (§3).

Challenges and why may Blockchain fail? Over-ordering could be desirable for the supplier,

even though it is wasteful from the system’s perspective. Therefore, unless the supplier is properly

compensated, the supplier might choose not to participate in a Blockchain system, depriving the

rest of the supply chain of information about this supplier’s state. Furthermore, the production

capacity depends on the supplier-buyer pair, and it is not perfectly substitutable among buyers,

14 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

requiring adjustments to be made by the supplier. The supplier may also have other considerations,

such as expanding strategic relationships with certain retailers. Therefore, the supplier may wish

to hinder the free trading of claims to its production capacity. We further discuss economic issues

related to incentives in §5.

What is the research potential? OM researchers can apply insights from the literature to

quantify the value of the Blockchain technology in managing the adverse consequences of the

Bullwhip effect. In particular, OM can inform the firms about the tradeoffs between efficiency

gains and competitive-advantage losses from sharing information. OM researchers can identify what

information needs to be collected and stored on the distributed ledger. For example, extending

work on transshipments (e.g., Anupindi et al. 2001) to supplier capacity sharing and understanding

the supplier’s costs, benefits, and incentives is also interesting.

4.2. Data Aggregation

Information flows in supply chains have been a major research topic in OM (Ha and Tang 2017).

Information visibility, aggregation, and validation (see §3) are the main ideas for the following

discussion. There are three directions for information flows: downstream (from suppliers and manufacturers to consumers), upstream (from consumers to manufacturers and suppliers), and multidirectional (up and down a supply chain, as well as to and from entities that are not directly

involved in a supply chain for a particular product).

In §4.1, we have discussed information about sales flowing upstream to suppliers and information about the supplier inventory flowing downstream to retailers. We add to these examples here.

Blockchain can help to provide more detailed data to consumers than is currently available. At

present, consumer-choice models use few factors that describe products (one dimension, aka “quality,” is ideal for analytical results), but in reality each product comes with a multi-dimensional and

complex history. Consider the simple act of buying mangos. Currently, consumers buy mangos in

supermarkets using simple information, such as their appearance, aroma, organic label, and price.

Imagine if consumers could learn where each container of mangos originated from, what fertilizers

and pesticides were used, what weather conditions occurred during the growing season, what labor

practices occurred, how long the container spent on the ship, in the port, etc. Blockchain technology promises to provide this information and companies, such as Walmart, would like to take

advantage of it. Walmart ran a pilot project of tracking mangos from Mexico to Walmart shelves.

The pilot involved 16 farms, two packing houses, three brokers, two import warehouses, and one

processing facility. Over the 30-day period, Walmart captured 23 different lot codes and tens of

thousands of sliced mangoes, according to a story by Jessica McKinzie10 If Blockchain technology

delivers, the consumer choice will become drastically more complex.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 15

Blockchain technology is great at aggregating information from multiple sources and information

of different natures. Recall the example of diamonds ledger from §1. For a diamond,11 a ledger

contains a record of a country of origin, a picture of the diamond after it was mined, a picture of a

KPC certificate12, professional information on individuals involved in diamond planning, cutting,

and polishing, videos of the diamond as it goes through the various steps of the production process,

a picture of the finished product, and finally a link to a GIA report.13 Information aggregation is

particularly relevant in the context of big data. The aggregated information can be used synergistically, improving system performance and reallocating benefits among participants. This may

prove particularly useful in the absence of formal markets. For example, consider a situation in

which electricity generators possess private information about equipment maintenance schedules,

consumers possess private information about their energy needs, and regulators have information

about the geographic distribution of pollution levels and effects. Consumers might be willing to

adjust their demand, but regulators and generators may not know about that flexibility. Electricity

producers might be willing to shift generation to a different fuel or a different plant, depending

on the current pollution conditions, and depending on the consumers’ willingness to adjust their

demand. Regulators might consider relaxing their requirements if the consumer needs are critical.

But, it can be difficult to combine all three (or more) streams of information. There are markets

that bring together consumers and generators, and there are markets where pollution credits are

traded (although not for all forms of pollutants). However, there is no market where all three

parties are present together. Conceivably, Blockchain technology can fill this gap.

How can Blockchain help? Blockchain technology provides a platform for combining information

from multiple sources (firms in a supply chain, regulators, and consumers) and over time without

the single centralized authority to control the process. This information is validated (§2.1.1 and

§3). Smart contracts (§2.1.2) can automate actions based on the aggregate information, reduce lead

times, and create markets where non-standardized resources are traded (§3). In a B2C context, this

makes the history of the product available for consumers’ purchase decisions. In a B2B context,

Blockchain creates a verified ledger of past transactions, which can be used by the buyers in the

supplier selection process or by the suppliers to signal their quality to the buyers. In B2T and

T2T transactions (where T stands for “Things” as in the “Internet of Things”), Blockchain can

integrate data from multiple smart sensors, share it with decision makers, and even automatically

execute contracts. For example, the mango pilot discussed above revealed that it took three days

for the mangoes to get from the customs broker to a processor, and that if Walmart could cut

down on that time, this would extend the shelf life of that product by a day or more, so that the

consumer gets fresher food, and consequently, there is less food waste.14

16 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Challenges and why may Blockchain fail? More data are not always better because data may

hide essential information. Consumers can be overwhelmed with additional data and either make

a bad choice or no choice at all. Furthermore, not all consumers want to know “how the sausage is

made” (literally, in some of the provenance applications, such as the provenance of pork products,

e.g., Nash 2016). More detailed information can lead to the fragmentation of the supplier market,

reducing supplier competition. The GIGO weakness discussed in §3 is a serious concern. Decision

makers need to trust that all data recorded by multiple firms on a distributed ledger correspond

to physical reality. The benefit of data aggregation depends on the willingness of various parties

to either participate in data sharing or to provide data truthfully.

What is the research potential? There are many interesting research questions. For instance,

how would consumers process multidimensional information? What information should be collected, recorded, and shared? How can product assortment be optimized when each product is

“unique,” once the history is taken into account? How should we write contracts that are based on

both aggregate market information and individual buyer and seller information? How should we

design systems to provide incentives for participants of supply chains to share information and to

do so truthfully? Does having more information exacerbate the GIGO problem, because there are

greater chances that incorrect information is present, or does it reduce the GIGO problem, because

of informational redundancy (information from some participants can be used to validate information provided by other participants)? Blockchain can formalize implicit relationships. In economics

and OM there are numerous studies of incomplete and relational contracts (Hart and Moore 1988,

Baker et al. 2002, Taylor and Plambeck 2007). Findings in the prior literature (e.g., Hilary and

Huang 2015) suggest that when interactions become more contractual and formal, the cooperation,

goodwill, and effort of the participants can decrease. As Blockchain technology practice develops,

researchers will need to develop the theory that captures the implicit vs explicit contracting effects

on effort in supply chains and on managing contracts that are more complex and dynamic. Lastly,

how should we aggregate individual needs and resources and repackage them to what market participants prefer to use (effectively collateralizing them)? What effect does this have on the social

welfare (the ability to shift consumption from lower utility to higher utility customers)?

4.3. Contract Automation

There are at least two potential benefits of automation through Blockchain. The first is the increased coordination through the supply chain. Imagine that a company operates a machine (e.g., a

robot on an assembly line) and that a sensor detects that a part in this machine is about to fail.

Ordering a replacement part ahead of the failure event will minimize the downtime. Currently,

some printer models automatically place an order for a replacement ink cartridge; some “smart”

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 17

refrigerators can order milk and other groceries. But the current technology is limited to communications between the “smart appliance” and the supplier of the part. It would be far more

beneficial if, in addition to alerting the immediate supplier of the part, the entire supply chain

received a signal to start the replenishment process. Furthermore, if the downtime of the machine

is unavoidable, customers who receive products manufactured on this machine should be informed

about the potential disruption to their supply. How should we make these communications credible? How should we reach beyond the immediate suppliers and customers? How can we do so

automatically? While machine maintenance and part replacement are classical problems in OM (a

survey of this area is Barlow and Proschan 1996), the integration between machine maintenance

and supply chain management is a less-researched topic, especially in the context of automation.

The second benefit of automation is the possibility for different parties to credibly commit

to future actions by making procurement contracts ex-post enforceable. Currently, buyers may

have a credibility problem when conveying their intentions to place large orders. Unless buyers

sign binding contracts (sometimes even if buyers signed binding contracts), they can renege on

the promises as new information becomes available. This clearly hurts the suppliers and makes

the initial communication from the buyers not fully credible. Smart contracts (§2.1.2) can make

commitment irreversible—when conditions are met, the orders will be automatically executed.

How can Blockchain help? Blockchain technology with smart contracts (§2.1.2) allows the

automatic activation of the entire supply chain. System-wide production, shipping, and inventory

decisions can be automated and synchronized. Information about orders and payments is verifiable

(§3). Automated contracts provide buyers with the commitment power.

Why may Blockchain fail? The complexity of automatic system optimization is tremendous.

Because of this complexity and because algorithms are placing orders, there is a risk that these

algorithms will make wrong decisions and humans will not realize this until it is too late and

damage has occurred. The “black box” weakness of the Blockchain technology (§3) is a significant

concern in the context of automation.

What is the research potential? What should the optimal policies look like in the presence of

smart contracts, where orders are placed with the entire upstream supply chains? What benefits

do they have compared to the current, less information-intensive policies? How should we take

advantage of the ability to commit to future minutely-specified actions in procurement contracting?

4.4. Supply Chain Risk Management

Supply chain risk management (SCRM) is important in practice. SCRM has been extensively

researched in the academic literature (see Aydin et al. 2012, Tomlin and Wang 2012). Academics

and industry practitioners have developed a good understanding of the SCRM process and what

18 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

the best practices are. In this subsection, we shall discuss Blockchain applications using the SCRM

process and best practices as the lens.

The steps of SCRM process are15 (1) identify risks, (2) prioritize them, (3) develop a treatment

plan, (4) reduce risk exposure ex-ante, (5) reduce risk impact ex-post, and (6) review the performance and learn. To expand this further, step (5), involves (a) recognizing that a risk event has

occurred, (b) collecting information, (c) assessing risk, (d) activating the plan, (e) informing stakeholders, (f) taking steps to contain the crisis, and (g) conducting a post-incident review. Figure 2

illustrates the process.

Supply Chain

Risk

Management

Process

1. Identify

Risks

2. Assess

&

prioritize

3. Develop

a

treatment

plan

4. Reduce

risk

exposure

5. Reduce

impact ex‐

post

6. Review

and learn

Visibility

Aggregation

Validation

Automation

Resiliency

Reduce

impact

ex‐post

(a)

Recognize

event

(b)

Collect

info.

(c) Assess

risk

(d)

Activate

plan

(e) Inform

stakehold

ers

(f) Contain

crisis

(g)

Conduct

review

Figure 2 SCRM process steps, Blockchain strengths, and reducing risk impact ex-post steps

4.4.1. Steps (1)-(4) of the SCRM Process. The conventional wisdom in SCRM practice

and theory is that risks often arise where no one is paying attention (Waters 2011). This often

means higher-tier suppliers, as numerous cases of product adulteration by subcontractors illustrate.

In 2007 Menu Foods issued a recall of its pet foods due to adulteration with melamine. The

culprit of adulteration was a Chinese subcontractor of a supplier of Menu Foods, ChemNutra Inc

(see discussion in Yang et al. 2009). It is important to note that Menu Foods was unaware that

ChemNutra had outsourced to a subcontractor. Another example (Hoyt et al. 2008) is that of the

Mattel toy recall in 2007 due to several defects, including the use of lead paint. Lee Der (a supplier

of Mattel) ordered paint from Dongxing, which was not on a list of approved paint suppliers at

Mattel. Dongxing purchased a batch of paint from the Internet. The paint came with a certificate

that it was lead-free, but this certificate was falsified. Similar to Menu Foods, Mattel did not have

visibility into the higher supply chain tiers. There are similar examples for Heparin, Austin Martin

cars, NATO airplanes and helicopters—higher tier subcontractors, whose identity is not known to

OEMs, introduce adulterated or counterfeit materials into supply chains (Haft 2015).

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 19

How can Blockchain help? Connecting the entire supply chain, from raw materials producers

to retailers, to a Blockchain platform can help companies to increase visibility into the structure

of their extended supply chains, identify factory locations, discover potential bottlenecks, and

unveil excessive geographic concentrations of production resources (§3). In fact, many current

applications of Blockchain technology are intended to establish product provenance. These include

(as we discussed earlier) tracking the movements of products through supply chains for fish,16

pork (Nash 2016), mangos,17 diamonds,18 and coffee (Naydenova 2017). This is instrumental in

identifying risks, estimating the probabilities of adverse events, and forecasting their consequences

(steps (1) and (2) of the SCRM process). For example, to assess the impact of a disruption, it is

helpful to aggregate information across the supply chain on backup capacities, and raw material

inventories. Thus forewarned, companies can prepare mitigation plans and take steps to forestall

supply disruptions and reduce their impact (step (3) of the SCRM process).

Tang and Babich (2014) argue that the lack of visibility is one of the key factors that contributed

to the surge in adulteration cases of products made in China in the late 2000s. Thus, if Blockchain

can increase visibility into supply chains, it will reduce some types of supply risk (step (4) of

the SCRM process). For example, if Menu Foods could trace where products are coming from, it

could detect the use of an unauthorized subcontractor. For instance, the identities of authorized

contractors can be stored on a ledger and if a company not on this list shows up in the chain of

custody for a product batch, smart contracts can alert the OEM of the deviation.

Challenges and why may Blockchain fail? Suppliers may resist the effort by OEMs to map

out the extended supply chains and discourage their own suppliers from joining the Blockchain

system. For example, Toyota’s car production was affected for months following the 2011 Japanese

earthquake. According to Greimel (2012), even after the disaster only half of 500 of Toyota’s tier-1

suppliers shared their supply chain information with Toyota, and the other half refused. Shinichi

Sasaki, Toyota’s global procurement chief, was quoted as saying: “Half of that is black-boxed to

us.”

Another potential negative for Blockchain is that by increasing the visibility and eliminating some

types of supply risks, Blockchain may encourage unethical suppliers to engage in other forms of risk

taking. For example, the reason unethical suppliers in China used melamine for the adulteration

of food products19 is that melamine increases the nitrogen count, which helps to fool the tests that

look for evidence of the dilution of products with water and because there were no tests directly

looking for the presence of melamine. One can argue that product inspections reduced the risk of

mild product adulteration with water, but increased the risk of serious product adulteration with

melamine. It is conceivable that Blockchain may have similar adverse effects.

20 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Another observation regarding possible Blockchain failures is that merely knowing the chain of

custody might be not be sufficient to eliminate adulteration. The Kobe Steel case illustrates that.

Business media reported in 2017 that Kobe’s employees falsified specifications for the company’s

aluminum and steel products. More than 500 of Kobe’s customers were affected, including Boeing,

Toyota, Honda, Nissan, and Ford. The use of Blockchain technology would not have prevented

this type of falsification. It is conceivable that adding smart sensors and smart contracts to keep

track of the composition of inputs and outputs from a factory might make cheating (e.g., for Kobe

employees) more difficult, but this is not obvious, and it requires additional investments.

What is the research potential? In the academic literature, Yang et al. (2009, 2012), Yang and

Babich (2014) are examples of papers that explore the role of information about supply disruptions

in managing supply chain risk. But the majority of researchers working on models with asymmetric

information in the context of SCRM consider single-tier systems. There is literature on multiechelon systems with random yields (see Sobel and Babich 2012 and references therein), but this

stream does not discuss the role of information. Advances in Blockchain technology may change

this. We hypothesize that when higher-tier suppliers’ identities are known to a larger retailer (like

Walmart), these suppliers would be less likely to cut corners on quality and risk their aspirations for

future business with this retailer. Related to this, tier-1 suppliers would be less likely to subcontract

to unauthorized firms. Although the frequency of supply risk events would decline, we suspect that

the potential impact of the events that do occur would be larger. Information about the overlap

of the extended supply chains affects strategic interactions among firms (Wadecki et al. 2012).

However, there is still relatively little academic research on this subject, in part because firms

have not had full visibility into their extended supply chains. Blockchain increases such strategic

interactions and demands further investigation.

4.4.2. Steps (5) and (6) of the SCRM Process. Let us consider how Blockchain might

be helpful in mitigating the impact of the disruption ex-post of the risk event (step 5). One of

the wisdoms in SCRM and crisis management is that it is essential to quickly recognize that an

adverse event has happened, deploy the response team, and inform the stakeholders.

How can Blockchain help? Monitoring the chain of custody for a product may trigger warnings when non-authorized sources are used. After a warning, potentially defective products can be

inspected and diverted away from downstream production stages and customers. This capability

would have been valuable in Menu Foods’ case. Knowing the chain of custody can also help companies to triangulate the source of the problem (to a particular supplier, factory, or workstation,

depending on the resolution power of Blockchain identity information). Blockchain can also help

to identify all customers affected by defects and those who are unaffected. The notifications can

be done automatically, using a “smart contract” feature (§2.1.2).

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 21

Smart contracts and validation features of Blockchain can activate crisis-response teams across

the entire supply chain. Production schedules can be changed, payments exchanged, and additional

workers deployed, all in response to automatic and credible signals. To a large extent, supply risks

mitigation plans can be put on smart contracts, freeing response teams to deal with non-standard,

unanticipated aspects of the disasters. In the Kobe Steel and Mitsubishi cases (McLain 2017),

the companies have not notified customers for months, while knowing that something was wrong

with the products. They could not determine the extent of the problem and did not wish to cause

confusion. Meanwhile, defective materials were used in trains, cars, ships, and the space shuttle.

One might wonder why they did not err on the side of caution and notify all customers. Unfortunately, this would also result in extensive economic damages to the customers, who would have

to idle their production lines unnecessarily, while the investigation is ongoing. Consider a food

safety application. While a food manufacturer investigates which batches of lettuce or mangos or

meat are contaminated, perishable products spoil and must be thrown away even if they were not

affected to begin with. To address the last SCRM process step (step (6)), Blockchain can aggregate information across the supply chain. This information is necessary to review mitigation plans’

effectiveness during the post-disruption debriefings and reviews.

Why may Blockchain fail? The reasons are similar to the ones discussed in §4.4.1.

What is the research potential? An interesting research question involves how to balance

under- and over-reaction to supply chain risk events, especially for those that are related to safety,

how and when to inform customers optimally, and how much benefit reducing investigation time

would bring to firms, customers, and society.

4.5. Blockchain in Ethical, Sustainable, and Responsible (ESR) Operations

ESR operations deal with important issues, such as labor conditions, child or involuntary labor,

the funding of wars, the avoidance of famines, and the responsible usage of natural resources (land,

water, energy), as they relate to operations decisions. Prominent examples in this area include,

on the negative side: the Nike child labor scandal, the Rana Plaza factory collapse in Bangladesh,

and blood diamonds in Africa. Examples on the positive side are Toyota’s efforts to reduce water

usage, micro-finance programs, and fair-trade programs.

How can Blockchain help? The promise of Blockchain technology is that knowing the provenance of goods can help to ascertain that production was performed in factories, which have

been certified as capable of ethical or environmentally-responsible operations. While this requires

the involvement of regulatory bodies (NGOs, governments, industry self-regulators) to conduct

the inspection and provide certifications, once certifications are in the Blockchain system, they

are immutable, and publicly visible, if ledgers are public, as in the case of diamonds ledger.20

22 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Certificates can be issued for a particular action (e.g., planting a certain number of trees, reducing emissions). If set up properly, Blockchain will ensure that these certificates cannot be copied,

double-counted, or illegally sold. This simplifies accounting processes and allows creating of markets where these immutable ESR claims are traded. For example, Veridium Labs is working on

implementing carbon offsets trading using Blockchain tokens (§2.2).21

Blockchain can help not only with tracing how products are manufactured, but also how they are

disposed of at the end of their useful lives, by tracking the product flow through reverse logistics

systems. The advantage of Blockchain technology is in providing the shared, low-cost platform for

multiple, unrelated companies, e.g., manufacturers, recyclers, landfill operators, logistics providers,

and regulators. Blockchain can aggregate information about a product’s journey from collection to

recycling and to landfills and validate this information.

Why may Blockchain fail? As with many applications of Blockchain to the physical world,

the weak point is where information is created and entered into the ledger, i.e., the “state-zero”

and GIGO problems. While the certificate indicating that trees were planted is incorruptible, can

we trust the person who vouched for this fact? Do we know that trees have not been cut since

the record was entered onto the ledger? If suppliers are certified to follow ethical practices, this

certificate is verifiable, but can we observe what practices are actually being followed?

What is the research potential? The tension between verified capabilities and verified actions

has been explored in the OM literature with regards to product adulteration (Babich and Tang

2012), but in general, an important research question involves providing a taxonomy of applications

in which trust in the capabilities is sufficient to also have trust in the execution.

4.6. Collateralizing Supply Chain Assets

OM researchers have studied the problem of achieving (frictionless) centralized outcomes in decentralized systems. Solutions include various coordinating contracts (Cachon 2003), internal markets

(Kouvelis and Lariviere 2000), and mechanism design (Sharma et al. 2008). The challenge with

contracts is that they are typically bilateral, whereas supply chain resources and demands are distributed across multiple firms, consumers, and regulators. The challenge with markets is that they

work best with standardized, commoditized, substitutable items, whereas a majority of corporate

and supply chain resources are customized.

To overcome the bilateral relations constraint, it would be helpful to issue claims (backed by

resources) with the property that anyone holding the claim, even if they are not in the contractual

relationship with the issuer, will receive what the claim promises.

To overcome the standardization constraint, it is necessary to aggregate information from multiple demand and supply sources for various resources and automatically match the demand with

the supply in an efficient way, accounting for the substitutability losses.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 23

How can Blockchain help? The validation dimension of the Blockchain will help to create digital

claims that can be circulated outside of the normal contracting relationships. The aggregation and

automation dimensions of Blockchain help to create a market for trading customized assets (§2.2

and §3).

For example, Blockchain technology allows the trading of claims on assets in different divisions in

corporations. This creates a substitute for internal corporate markets. Suppose various divisions of

a corporation need raw materials, such as aluminum, or parts, such as fasteners. The procurement

division can purchase those from the outside and then issue digital claims on them that can be

traded among various product lines in a corporation, capturing relative needs for the product of

each one. Moreover, a corporation can create digital tokens to be used not just internally, but

also externally with the suppliers. If some division needs to purchase components from the outside

supplier, the division can give the supplier Blockchain tokens, as headquarters have validated the

existence of assets behind the tokens. Effectively, each company will be able to create its own

internal currency and collateralize it with assets, so that the outside world can accept them in lieu

of cash payments. Suppliers can use the same tokens to pay their suppliers, etc. Liquidity (i.e.,

availability of cash) constraints in supply chains will thus be reduced.

How may Blockchain fail? External verification of the value of corporate assets is needed before

they can be used as collateral (this is less of an issue for internal markets). In addition, as the

recent financial crisis demonstrated, collateralized assets and risks make it more difficult for the

market participants to assess risk exposure. This is true when collateralization is used for relatively

standardized securities, like mortgages, and where collateralization is performed by humans. If an

algorithm performs the collateralization and if risks that are aggregated are not standard, the

possibility of being exposed to the “model risk” is very high.

What is the research potential? How should tokenization be implemented? What assets can be

traded this way? How can informational discrepancies be overcome when creating such markets?

4.7. Blockchain Queueing and Optimization

As we discussed in the technology section (§2), optimizing Blockchain platforms will be difficult

and important. For example, the tradeoffs and interplay among multiple factors, such as processing

speed, memory scalability, information processing costs, data pool liquidity, and privacy level, need

to be understood and taken into account to achieve efficient operations of distributed ledgers.

Consider, for instance, Bitcoin Blockchain (for details on Bitcoin technology, see Nakamoto 2008).

The time it takes to complete a transfer from one Bitcoin wallet to another one can be analyzed

using queueing theory. On average, it takes 10 minutes to “mine” a block, i.e., solve a cryptographic

puzzle that allows a miner to record transactions. The actual mining time is random. The apparent

24 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

inefficiency in the mining process actually plays an important role in providing the immutability

of records of past transactions (§2). The size of each block is hard-coded to be 1MB (currently).

There is a tradeoff in choosing the block size. Larger blocks allow more transactions to be recorded.

However, larger blocks may increase system latency, when being distributed among nodes of the

Blockchain network. What goes into blocks is important as well. Pointers to outside data are highly

space efficient, but expose the system to the possibility that data to which those pointers point

will be modified without the network’s knowledge.

The transactions are waiting in a queue to be recorded. Depending on the demand for recording

transactions, the size of this queue can be quite long (Figure 3). Miners might put transactions at

the head of the queue for additional fees. Therefore, the queueing protocol and miner incentives are

important for the analysis. Bitcoin Blockchain and Etherium Blockchain are used for recording all

kinds of transactions by many companies. For example, the number of pending transaction on the

Etherium network increased six fold in weeks following the launch of CryptoKitties because the

total demand for CryptoKitties transactions spiked at about 10-15% of the total network traffic.22

0

40000

80000

120000

160000

200000

Number of transactions waiting for confirmation

Figure 3 Unconfirmed transactions queue dynamics (Data source: blockchain.info)

Blockchain structures are becoming more complex and non-linear. Multi-layer structures, such

as the side chains we discuss in the §2 (e.g., Lighting), are likely to become common. To some

extent, this optimization is a computer science problem23. However, OM researchers also have a

role to play in modeling, analyzing, and optimizing Blockchain network performance.

What is the research potential? Understanding the dynamics of demand, the supply (capacity constraints on block size and the stochastic nature of mining), and their interplay with queue

waiting time are essential for the analysis of applications. OM researchers have the right tools to

apply to this task.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 25

5. Economics of Blockchain in Supply Chains

With the development of Blockchain technology, the economics of the firm will be affected. For

example, Coasian transaction costs (Coase 1937) may be reduced. Blockchain may also affect the

Grossman-Hart-Moore model (Grossman and Hart 1986, Hart and Moore 1988) by enabling or

forcing a greater degree of contract completeness. This may have implications for labor economics

and management. If independent contractors become more prevalent, for example, telework may

become more common. Compensation contracts may have to be altered. These developments may

also have implications for OM researchers. For example, an increase in the number of contractors

working on remote networks may affect supply chain’s robustness. On the finance side, ICOs have

the potential to change the way firms are funded (see Chod and Lyandres 2018 and Catalini and

Gans 2018 for two recent example of how this can affect R&D financing). We elaborate more on

these themes in the next two sub-sections by discussing two specific topics in greater detail.

5.1. Economics of Information, Contracts, and Governance

Blockchain technology has the potential to change the economic or even legal structure of supply

chains. Traditionally, supply chains were organized along two mutually exclusive models. The

first model is integrated within an entity (e.g., a company) and it relies on a central planner

(e.g., the headquarters) to optimize SC structure through fiat. The second one is a decentralized

model in which different entities form a chain of contracts and flows. Blockchain networks offer

an intermediate step that facilitates supply chain optimization without a full integration. This is

achieved by creating an institution (i.e., a network) that exists in its own right.

This raises two questions. The first is what level of integration leads to a solution closer to the

“first-best” one. For example, scholars can investigate whether Blockchain provides advantages

over the existing systems, such as a centralized database housed within a company or a regulatory

body, and what these advantages are. The argument in favor of Blockchain is that in most reallife supply chain applications, several parties are involved in the manufacturing and selling of

products. The more parties are involved, the greater are the costs of sharing information among

them credibly. The cost depends (in part) on the incentives to misrepresent information. The field

of information economics describes the importance of information costs. However, the issue that

requires exploration is the connection between the size of the supply network and these costs. This

approach requires researchers to go beyond the standard principal-agent framework.

The second question is how to govern institutions associated with Blockchain technology networks. At the macro-level, structures have to be developed to ensure that the technology is working

seamlessly across applications. The Internet went through a similar process and the Internet Corporation for Assigned Names and Numbers (ICANN) was created as a consequence. Aside from

26 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

understanding the factors that allow a technology to flourish, this issue is relevant for OM scholars

because a breakdown of the eco-system around Blockchain technology can create risks for supply

chains. At the micro-level, once Blockchain networks become institutions, they need a form of governance for their efficient implementation (Levinson and Marzouki 2015). For example, they need

structures to make decisions, rules to implement them, and procedures to verify their enforcements.

The economic analysis of institutions become relevant for supply chain scholars. For example, the

following questions become important: How do we allocate voting rights in consensus-forming decisions? Should they be aligned with cash flow rights? If not, how do we address this separation

between the two? Should a network have legal rights and obligations as such, or should only the

members be granted these right and responsibilities? These governance issues have been explored

by scholars in accounting, economics, law, and other social sciences. However, the development of

Blockchain technology opens an entirely new venue for OM researchers.

5.2. Industrial Organization of Blockchain

One way to approach this area is to distinguish among horizontalities, verticalities, and diagonalities. We define a horizontality as an organizational structure in which all parties are operating

at the same level, for example, a spot market. Markets differ in their depth (trade volume and

the number of traders). If there are many traders and the volume of trades is large, such as in

the case of wheat and corn, there exist centralized exchanges (e.g., CME Group) where clearing

occurs and standardized contracts are written and traded. If highly liquid exchanges already exist,

Blockchain technology is unlikely to offer much additional benefit. Although centralized exchanges

are expensive to setup initially, their per-transaction costs are typically lower than those of Blockchain. Then, there are markets that are extremely decentralized and unstructured. Their low depth

and liquidity makes it uneconomical to set up centralized trading platforms. For such goods and

services, Blockchain technology offers a way of creating digital claims and processing the exchange

of those claims for payments by requiring a lower setup cost than the one of a centralized system.

For example, while there are derivative contracts (futures and options) on long-grain rough rice,

traded on CME, there are no contracts for African rice, whose potential trade volume is smaller.

Blockchain technology can help to create and operate this market, improving the efficiency for

those using, growing, and trading this type of rice.

We define a verticality as the organizational structure in which processes are sequentially ordered

and often integrated through a collection of contracts. Supply chains are often verticalities in

which suppliers are arranged in tiers (this structure is described in the classical multi-echelon serial

supply chain systems). As discussed above, Blockchain is likely to improve different dimensions

associated with verticalities. For example, the ability to better observe the state of the supply chain

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 27

mitigates the need for inventory. In addition, assets located in different tiers of a supply chain can

be collateralized more easily and claims on them can be traded within the supply chain. Overall,

these different features may reduce the Bullwhip effect.

Blockchain is also likely to affect diagonalities, a complex hybrid system in which horizontalities

(e.g., spot markets) and verticalities (e.g., supply chains) are coming together. Imagine a consumer

orders a toy from a supermarket. A delivery person (hired from a pool of independent contractors)

picks up the item, orders a car, and delivers it. The door has a smart lock and opens if the

right person with the right code shows up at the right time with the right product. The toy is

recorded in a database, in case it needs to be serviced or recalled. This complex supply chain

needs to integrate multiple parts: the traditional supply chain of the supermarket (possibly with

inter-modal transportations from overseas), different marketplaces to secure the delivery person

and the car, the IoT to open the door, and a registry to keep track of the product after its sales.

Smart contracts (§2.1.2) may facilitate these interactions, but the technical uncertainty (§3) may

preclude full integration.

Amazon has recently started to offer a product similar to the one described in the above paragraph, but with a different approach. The Seattle-based company has fully integrated the service

(successfully or not, time will tell). In contrast, in the diagonality that we describe, one company

would not be in control of everything, e.g., Amazon would not own smart locks, items would not

have to be purchased from Amazon, and the delivery person would not work for Amazon. The

Blockchain revolution will not have one company (e.g., Amazon) at the center of the process, but

rather independent entities interacting in the decentralized fashion with the same (or better) effect.

By allowing separate completion for specific parts of the bundle, it is possible for the delivery to

become more effective. Conditions under which this statement is true are worth investigating.

In other situations, a traditional vertical supply chain can be integrated with shipping portals,

a trade financing markets, or with a registry of asset ownership post-delivery. For example, it

may be worth investigating how firms acquire and maintain market power when the concept of

“market power” is extended beyond simple markets. Anti-trust scholars have considered the effects

of mergers on specific markets, in particular in the context of the acquisitions of suppliers or

customers. The OM literature (Hu and Sobel 2005, Federgruen and Hu 2016, and Federgruen and

Hu 2017) has also considered the effect of competition among entire supply chains. Blockchain has

the potential to reframe these questions in environments with unprecedented complexity.

6. Conclusions

Blockchain technology is built around the concept of a distributed digital ledger. The technological

implementation of this concept varies and is not yet stable. Bitcoin was the first application.

28 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

However, by now, there are literally thousands of others (and the association of Blockchain with

crypto-currencies may have some negative social connotations). Many of the recent developments

are salient for the OM research community. In this article, we provided a research agenda for the

OM field. There are many promising and exciting business models and new perspectives on the

classical OM problems. At the same time, we caution against falling for the hype about Blockchain.

The technology is still emerging, and most projects will fail. For many situations, a centralized

database is more efficient. The state zero problem is a major issue. Sensors and trusted auditors

can help, but they will not entirely solve the problem. Although in some applications collecting

data through sensors is the main challenge, in others validating stored data is more important.

Blockchain can improve supply chain operations by providing visibility, information aggregation,

information validation, contract automation, and system resiliency. Blockchain can create more

stable, transparent, secured, efficient, ethical, and robust supply chains. Blockchain can facilitate

the integration of supply chains and finance. We observe the first real-life implementations, but

many practical and theoretical questions remain unanswered.

Aside from offering new interesting ways to revisit the traditional OM questions, Blockchain

offers the potential to introduce new perspectives. For example, with private Blockchain networks,

supply chains become more than an integrated collection of flows and contracts; they become

institutions that need to be regulated and governed as such. Blockchain development also creates

interesting issues from an industrial organization perspective.

Overall, Blockchain is an emerging technology that has the potential to disrupt OM. Naturally,

similar claims have been made before. In some cases, this initial enthusiasm was warranted (e.g.,

TCP/IP and the Internet), but in other cases (ERP, RFID), the consequences of new technologies

were more limited. One thing is clear, however: more research is required.

References

Anupindi R, Bassok Y, Zemel E (2001) A general framework for the study of decentralized distribution

systems. M&SOM 3(4):349–368.

Aydin G, Babich V, Beil DR, Yang Z (2012) Decentralized supply risk management. Kouvelis P, Boyabatli

O, Dong L, Li R, eds., Handbook of Integrated Risk Management in Global Supply Chains, chapter 14,

389–424 (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc).

Babich V (2006) Vulnerable options in supply chains: Effects of supplier competition. Nav Res Log 53(7):656–

673.

Babich V, Hilary G (2018a) Blockchain and other distributed ledger technologies in operations, working

paper, available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3232977.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 29

Babich V, Hilary G (2018b) Supplemental materials for distributed ledgers and operations: What

operations management researchers should know about blockchain technology, available at

https://ssrn.com/abstract=3237538.

Babich V, Kouvelis P (2018) Introduction to the special issue on research at the interface of finance, operations, and risk management (iFORM): Recent contributions and future directions. M&SOM 20(1):1–18.

Babich V, Tang CS (2012) Managing opportunistic supplier product adulteration: Deferred payments,

inspection, and combined mechanisms. M&SOM 14(2):301–314.

Baker G, Gibbons R, Murphy KJ (2002) Relational contracts and the theory of the firm. Q J Econ 117(1):39–

84.

Bank for International Settlements (2014) Trade finance: Developments and issues. publication 50, Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), Basel.

Barlow RE, Proschan F (1996) Mathematical theory of reliability, volume 17 (Siam).

Barnes-Schuster D, Bassok Y, Anupindi R (2002) Coordination and flexibility in supply contracts with

options. M&SOM 4(3):171–207.

Berkrot B (2012) Fake Avastin shows little protection of drug supply. URL goo.gl/NB2r8J, Mar 12, 2012.

Browne R (2017) There were more than 26,000 new blockchain projects last year - only 8% are still active.

URL http://cnb.cx/2FCWEh3, November 9, 2017. Accessed on Feb 26, 2018.

Cachon GP (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. de Kok A, Graves SC, eds., Supply Chain

Management: Design, Coordination and Operation, chapter 6 (Elsevier).

Catalini C, Gans JS (2018) Initial coin offerings and the value of crypto tokens. Technical report, National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Chen F, Drezner Z, Ryan JK, Simchi-Levi D (2000) Quantifying the bullwhip effect in a simple supply chain:

The impact of forecasting, lead times, and information. Manage Sci 46(3):436–443.

Chod J, Lyandres E (2018) A theory of ICOs: Diversification, agency, and information asymmetry. http:

//dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3159528.

Chod J, Trichakis N, Tsoukalas G, Aspegren H, Weber M (2018) Blockchain and the value of operational

transparency for supply chain finance. Working paper, MIT.

Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16):386–405.

Dorri A, Kanhere SS, Jurdak R (2017) Towards an optimized blockchain for iot. Proceedings of the Second

International Conference on Internet-of-Things Design and Implementation, 173–178 (ACM).

Dyble J (2017) Canada urged by IBM to use blockchain in the distribution of legal cannabis. Digital Supply

Chain URL https://shar.es/1LWxfF, Nov 7, 2017. Accessed on Feb 26, 2018.

Federgruen A, Hu M (2016) Sequential multiproduct price competition in supply chain networks. Oper Res

64(1):135–149.

30 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Federgruen A, Hu M (2017) Competition in multi-echelon systems. INFORMS Tutorials in Operations Research .

Garc´ıa-Ba˜nuelos L, Ponomarev A, Dumas M, Weber I (2017) Optimized execution of business processes on

blockchain. International Conference on Business Process Management, 130–146 (Springer).

Greimel H (2012) Tsunami: The aftermath. URL https://goo.gl/rEWUDo, Mar 12, 2012.

Grossman SJ, Hart OD (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94(4):691–719.

Ha AY, Tang CS (2017) Handbook of Information Exchange in Supply Chain Management (Springer).

Haft JR (2015) Unmade in China: The Hidden Truth about China’s Economic Miracle (John Wiley & Sons).

Hart O, Moore J (1988) Incomplete contracts and renegotiation. Econometrica 755–785.

Hilary G (2015) The end of human risk management? URL https://goo.gl/aMsBJ6, November 23, 2015.

Hilary G (2018) Blockchain and other distributed ledger technologies, an advanced primer. Working paper,

Georgetown University.

Hilary G, Huang S (2015) Trust and contracting, URL https://ssrn.com/abstract=2604974.

Hilary G, Liu LX (2018) Distributed ledgers and finance, working paper.

Hoyt D, Lee HL, Tseng MM (2008) Unsafe for children: Mattel’s toy recalls and supply chain management.

GS-63.

Hu QJ, Sobel MJ (2005) Supply chain games, working paper.

Kouvelis P, Lariviere MA (2000) Decentralizing cross-functional decisions: Coordination through internal

markets. Manage Sci 46(8):1049–1058.

Lee HL, Padmanabhan V, Whang S (1997) Information distortion in a supply chain: The bullwhip effect.

Manage Sci 43(4):546–558.

Levinson NS, Marzouki M (2015) Internet governance institutionalization: Process and trajectories. Global

Governance Facing Structural Changes, 17–35 (Springer).

McLain S (2017) Mitsubishi materials’ quality scandal kept quiet for months. URL https://goo.gl/C3Hdsu,

WSJ, Nov 24, 2017. Accessed on Feb 26, 2018.

Moise I (2018) Maersk and ibm partner on blockchain for global trade. WSJ Jan 16, https://www.wsj.

com/articles/maersk-and-ibm-partner-on-blockchain-for-global-trade-1516111543.

Nakamoto S (2008) Bitcoin: A peer-to-peer electronic cash system .

Nash KS (2016) Wal-mart turns to blockchain for tracking pork in china. WSJ Oct 19, https://blogs.

wsj.com/cio/2016/10/19/wal-mart-turns-to-blockchain-for-tracking-pork-in-china/.

Naydenova M (2017) The world’s first traceable coffee – blockchain revolution. URL https://goo.gl/

ZWYA78, Nov 7, 2017.

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 31

Sharma S, Babich V, Teneketzis D, Van Oyen M (2008) A mechanism to implement the optimal centralized

solution of a supply-chain problem in Nash equilibria, University of Michigan.

Sobel MJ, Babich V (2012) Optimality of myopic policies for dynamic lot-sizing problems in serial production

lines with random yields and autoregressive demand. Oper Res 60(6):1520–1536.

Tang CS, Babich V (2014) Using social and economic incentives to discourage chinese suppliers from product

adulteration. Bus Horizons 57(4):497–508.

Taylor TA, Plambeck EL (2007) Supply chain relationships and contracts: The impact of repeated interaction

on capacity investment and procurement. Manage Sci 53(10):1577–1593.

Tomlin B, Wang Y (2012) Operational strategies for managing supply chain disruption risk. Kouvelis P,

Boyabatli O, Dong L, Li R, eds., Handbook of Integrated Risk Management in Global Supply Chains.

Wadecki A, Babich V, Wu O (2012) Manufacturers’ competition and subsidies to suppliers. Gurnani H,

Mehrotra A, Ray S, eds., Managing Supply Disruptions, 141–163 (London: Springer-Verlag Ltd.).

Wall M (2016) Counterfeit drugs: ‘people are dying every day’. URL http://www.bbc.com/news/

business-37470667, 27 September 2016. Accessed on Feb 26, 2018.

Waters D (2011) Supply chain risk management: vulnerability and resilience in logistics (Kogan Page Pub.).

Yang Z, Aydin G, Babich V, Beil D (2009) Supply disruptions, asymmetric information, and a backup

production option. Manage Sci 55(2):192–209.

Yang Z, Aydin G, Babich V, Beil D (2012) Using a dual-sourcing option in the presence of asymmetric

information about supplier reliability: Competition vs. diversification. M&SOM 14(2):202–217.

Yang Z, Babich V (2014) Does a procurement service provider generate value for the buyer through information about supply risks? Manage Sci 61(5):979–998.

Notes

1https://www.gmaonline.org/news-events/newsroom/the-grocery-manufacturers-association-gma-and-battellelaunch-tool-to-/

2https://www.hyperledger.org/projects/sawtooth/seafood-case-study

3https://goo.gl/4Bz1JJ

4https://www.everledger.io

5https://www.marketwatch.com/story/ibm-and-veridium-labs-partner-to-use-blockchain-technology-to-improvecarbon-credit-markets-2018-05-15

6https://www.cbinsights.com/research/blockchain-hype-stock-trends/

7

available at Babich and Hilary (2018b)

8

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ethereum

9Other technologies, such as RFID, were proposed as solutions to the Bullwhip effect. We discuss our view on the

relationship between the Blockchain and other technologies, including RFID in §§2 and 6.

10https://newfoodeconomy.org/blockchain-food-traceability-walmart-ibm/

11https://diamonds.everledger.io/search/QSLIS013

32 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

12Kimberley Process Certification Scheme (KPCS) safeguards the shipment of rough diamonds’ and certifies them

as conflict free.

13Gemological Institute of America, https://www.gia.edu/.

14https://newfoodeconomy.org/blockchain-food-traceability-walmart-ibm/

15Adopted from the best practices documented at http://www.scrlc.com/ and from Waters (2011).

16https://www.hyperledger.org/projects/sawtooth/seafood-case-study

17https://newfoodeconomy.org/blockchain-food-traceability-walmart-ibm/

18https://www.everledger.io

19http://www.who.int/csr/media/faq/QAmelamine/en/

20https://diamonds.everledger.io/search/QSLIS013

21https://www.marketwatch.com/story/ibm-and-veridium-labs-partner-to-use-blockchain-technology-to-improvecarbon-credit-markets-2018-05-15

22http://www.bbc.com/news/technology-42237162

23See Dorri et al. (2017) or Garc´ıa-Ba˜nuelos et al. (2017) for recent examples

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 1

Supplemental Materials for “Distributed Ledgers and

Operations: What Operations Management Researchers

Should Know about Blockchain Technology”

Appendix A: Applications of Blockchain to Bitcoin

Bitcoin is the first successful system that eschewed a central authority for issuing currency, transferring

ownership, and confirming transactions electronically. Bitcoin Blockchain, the technology supporting this

system, is a distributed digital ledger that can record transactions between two parties in a verifiable and

permanent way. The records cannot be altered retroactively without altering all subsequent blocks and

obtaining the agreement of the network. Blockchain is based on a peer-to-peer network of nodes collectively

adhering to a protocol for validating new blocks. Blocks contain “facts,” such as transactions.

Bitcoin Blockchain is essentially the combination of a peer-to-peer (P2P) software (comparable to BitTorrent) with a public key cryptographic tool (comparable to Pretty Good Privacy). As in other Blockchain

technologies, it is consensus based to protect its integrity. It consists of two kinds of records: transactions

and blocks. Blocks hold batches of valid transactions and additional information necessary for the system to

work. For example, each block includes information necessary to link it to the previous block.

The normal process flow for updating the Bitcoin ledger is the following. A party requests a transaction

involving the transfer of Bitcoins to another party. The requested transaction is broadcast over a P2P

network. The nodes validate the transaction in terms of compliance with the Blockchain’s rules, the digital

signature, and any conflicts with previously seen transactions. If a transaction is validated, it enters that

node’s local list of provisional unconfirmed transactions. Transactions that are not validated are rejected.

To do this validation, the nodes employ an algorithm (based on public-key cryptography). The signature

of a transaction is used as an input in the next transaction. This ensures that all individual transactions

are linked to each other (in a tree-like structure). The use of robust cryptographic tools combined with the

database replication provides resiliency.

However, this procedure by itself does not guarantee that double-spending is impossible. Double-spending is

when a bad actor spends the same resources twice by sending multiple orders in rapid succession. Centralized

databases can easily prevent this, but the fact that the ledger is distributed may hinder a timely verification.

To address this issue, transactions are grouped in blocks that are time stamped. These blocks are ordered

in a single chain that is replicated over the entire network. Once verified the transaction is combined with

other transactions to create a new time-stamped block of data for the ledger. The new block is then added

to the existing Blockchain in a way that is permanent and unalterable (each block contains a link to the

previous block. It takes about 10 minutes to produce a Bitcoin block, and three to seven transactions can

be added to a block per second. For other Blockchain applications, blocks are recorded at a higher pace, in

a matter of seconds. Transactions are pending until they are confirmed, but they are not lost. At worst, the

stamping of these transactions is delayed slightly.

The consensus mechanism in the Bitcoin Blockchain is PoW (described in §2). An agent could theoretically

alter the Blockchain history, but with PoW, they would also need to have the majority of the computational

2 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

power in the network to do so. Because the Bitcoin network currently benefits from a colossal amount of

computation power, it would be extremely difficult for an attacker to break the network by brute force.

This protects the immutability of the record (in this form of Blockchain). PoW is expensive in terms of the

computational cost, but this cost is precisely what makes the network resistant to attacks. Each additional

block makes the ledger more robust by exponentially increasing the number of computations necessary to

alter it. Further discussion of Blockchain technology can be found in Hilary (2018).

Appendix B: Additional Ideas for the Research Agenda of Blockchain Technology

in OM

B.1. Crisis Management

Figure B.1 depicts the steps of crisis management. These steps resemble steps comprising responses to a

SCRM event ex-post. In fact, this figure comes from the SCRM best-practices document. This is not surprising because ex-post responses usually involve dealing with a crisis. However, the insights apply generally to

any crisis (not just in supply chains).

Figure B.1 Crisis Management Sequence

Source: SCRM Best Practices, Section 5 (http://www.scrlc.com/articles/Supply_Chain_Risk_Management_A_

Compilation_of_Best_Practices_final[1].pdf)

There are two features that differentiate crisis management from risk management. First, during a crisis,

time usually becomes a bottleneck resource. For example, as a pandemic spreads or as a population is

awaiting help after a natural disaster or as production capacity is idling, the damage accumulates with every

passing second. Any steps and resources that can shorten the duration of a crisis are beneficial. This includes

recognizing that the crisis is happening sooner, not wasting time during the collection of information and the

assessment of risk, having a crisis response plan in place, activating a crisis team, and notifying stakeholders

without delays. Second, during a crisis the risk management infrastructure itself can be affected, including

personnel, computer and communication systems, civil infrastructure, as well as law enforcement and the

legal system.

How can Blockchain help? Similar to our explanation of the role of Blockchain in SCRM, the strengths of

Blockchain in providing visibility, aggregating information, validating it, automating execution, and system

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 3

resiliency are instrumental for crisis management. In fact, Blockchain can be even more beneficial for crisis

management than for general SCRM. Taking advantage of smart contracts, stakeholders, and crisis management teams can be automatically notified about unfolding crises and sent updates about the mitigation

progress. Blockchain can integrate information from a variety of sources. It can provide temporary identities

to the population affected by a crisis or by response personnel to facilitate the tracking of resource usage

and consumption. The distributed nature of Blockchain technologies make them more robust to some types

of infrastructure losses (as discussed in §2).

Why may Blockchain fail? Alas, Blockchain does require basic infrastructure to operate. For example, if

electricity is out, the plans for disaster response might not reach personnel and stakeholders in the affected

areas.

What is the research potential? What effect would temporary identities have on resource management?

How does this relate to humanitarian logistics research? Is automating the crisis response increasing or

decreasing risk (Hilary 2015)?

B.2. Tokenization and Capacity Management

Claims in the form of Blockchain tokens can be written and traded not only on assets, but also on capacity or

reorder options. OM researchers have studied the use and value of reorder options in procurement contracting

(Barnes-Schuster et al. 2002, Babich 2006).

How can Blockchain help? Blockchain technology can help creating a secondary market for trading

tokens represeting reorder options and other forms of contract flexibility, similar to what Blockchain did for

financial options and other financial securities. Blockchain eliminates the need for the exchange to serve as

middlemen. Retailers that anticipate a higher demand can purchase additional reorder options from other

retailers, rather than from the manufacturer. This allows for more efficient reallocation of risk (risk pooling).

This also makes options more valuable and the retailers more likely to order them.

Another application of Blockchain technology for creating digital claims is to keep track of the ownership

of products after they have been sold. By keeping track of after-sales transactions, the manufacturers can

contact the current owner of the product to control the operations of gray markets (i.e., the sales of genuine

products by unauthorized retailers) and to administer warranty and reward programs. Customers too can

benefit from knowing the history of the products after the sale by the OEM. The history of second-hand

products can signal quality (e.g., has the car been in the flood zone during a hurricane? Has the medicine

been kept in dark, cool place for the duration of its life?). The validation and aggregation dimensions of

Blockchain technology are essential for this application.

Why may Blockchain fail? Firms or customers may prefer less information to be available. It is far from

obvious that more information would produce a better equilibrium. For example, manufacturers may tacitly

approve of the existence of the gray markets if they can pretend not to know about them.

What is the research potential? How can the market be implemented for non-standard claims? What

are the rules for matching the demand and supply over time? How much of the multi-item inventory theory

can be used for managing such markets? What would be the effect of secondary markets on the equilibrium

purchases of reorder options? How should manufacturers adjust option prices to account for the presence

4 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

of the secondary market? What degree of risk pooling can be achieved, and can the manufacturer avoid

excessive capacity overinvestments?

B.3. Blockchain in Supply Chain Finance

Blockchain technology has the potential to integrate supply chain management with other functions. For

example, supply chain finance (SCF) is an important area of OM research (Babich and Kouvelis 2018).

The practice of SCF represents a sizeable part of the economy. For example, the Bank for International

Settlements (2014) reports that trade credit accounts for $12 trillion out of $18 trillion in exports per year.

SCF allows companies to use working capital more effectively and reduce financing costs by streamlining

transactions between banks, using the credit capacity and the cost of firms with lower capital costs, and

incorporating information about procurement and logistics processes. SCF solutions are typically offered

by intermediaries: banks, logistics providers, and technology companies, who provide their service for a fee.

Current SCF solutions typically apply to a single tier of a supply chain. SCF solutions are themselves an

improvement over the millennia-old ways of conducting business transactions, such as letters of credit and

escrow services. Letters of credit guarantee that the buyer of goods or services has financial resources to pay

(either cash or the approved line of credit). Both with letters of credit and escrow accounts, a third party

(e.g., a bank) holds the money until sales conditions have been met. Business transactions using letters of

credit take a long time (days or weeks), because multiple parties need to verify different information. The

following is a typical process. First, the buyer applies for a letter of credit from its bank. Second, the buyer’s

bank provides the letter of credit to the seller. Third, the seller ships the goods with the carrier and supplies

a confirmation (e.g., bill of lading) to the seller’s bank together with the letter of credit. Fourth, the seller’s

bank pays the seller and sends the letter of credit to the buyer’s bank, which wires the money to the seller’s

bank. Fifth, the buyer’s bank sends the bill to the buyer. Finally, the buyer uses the confirmation of payment

to receive goods from the carrier. SCF solutions put information about sales and payment on one platform

and expedite the money flow from the buyer to the seller. Potentially, SCF solutions take over the functions

of both the buyer’s and the seller’s banks in providing escrow services to the transaction.

How can Blockchain help? It can help to bypass the traditional SCF providers and offer SCF solutions

along extended supply chains. Fundamentally, many SCF solutions are focused on establishing credibly that

the sellers of goods have produced and shipped them and that the buyers of goods have committed capital

to pay for the goods and on collecting and utilizing information about creditworthiness of either the buyer

or the supplier. This is an ideal application for Blockchain technologies, where claims on the ownership of

the products are exchanged for claims of the ownership of some amount of cash and where information is

aggregated from different sources over time. Furthermore, the marginal cost of adding participants to a SCF

ledger can be lower than with a solution provided by a traditional SCF provider. FnConn, a subsidiary

of FoxConn, announced in 2017 a launch of a Blockchain-based platform for providing working capital to

firms in FoxConn’s supply chain. The announcement mentioned loans totaling $6.5 million have already been

issued.24

Even when using traditional SCF providers, Blockchain strengths (§3) in increasing visibility into higher

supply chain tiers, aggregating various information, helps to overcome asymmetric information and moral

Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM 5

hazard costs that might be restricting access to financing currently. For example, according to Sanne Wass,25

new pilots by Unilever, Sainsbury’s, and Sappi together with Barclays, Standard Chartered, and BNP Paribas

will try to use Blockchain to record environmental impact information of supply chains and tie it with making

financing available to companies. One of the pilots is focused on tea supply chains, and the participants hope

to include information about 10,000 Malawian tea farmers.

Why may Blockchain fail? Some companies are reluctant to participate in SCF solutions (regardless of

whether they are done through a bank or a Blockchain). Weak suppliers may feel that better information

may allow more powerful buyers to take advantage of them (now or in the future), by reducing information

asymmetry, unveiling their supply sources, etc. Companies might not want to share SCF benefits with

suppliers because helping a supplier also helps competitors, who share the same supplier (Wadecki et al.

2012).

What is the research potential? How can multi-firm SCF solutions be optimally managed? How can

competitive effects between supply chains and between individual firms be accounted for? What SCF contracts can be created using more detailed information generated by Blockchain networks? There is already

an initial work in OM literature on this subject. Chod et al. (2018) study how blockchain technology and

the transaction verifiability it affords can be leveraged by firms to efficiently alleviate information asymmetry issues between themselves and their prospective lenders for supply chain finance. But more research is

needed. For discussion of Distributed Ledgers in Finance see Hilary and Liu (2018).

Appendix C: Blockchain examples used in the paper

We used the following Blockchain examples in this article.

6 Babich, Hilary: Blockchain for OM

Table C.1 Blockchain examples used in the paper

Name Description First

mention

Cannabis IBM proposed to the government of British Columbia to use

Blockchain technology to verify the provenance of legal cannabis §1

Fish Track the provenance and the chain of custody of fish §1

Coffee Track the provenance and the chain of custody of coffee §1

Global food

supply chain

A consortium of companies, led by Walmart, will work with IBM

to identify where global food supply chains can benefit from

Blockchain

§1

Pork Walmart has piloted the use Blockchain to track pork in China §1

Diamonds Since 2015, Everledger has recorded the provenance and the chain

of custody of over 2 million diamonds on a Blockchain §1

Global trade Maersk and IBM created a joint venture for creating a more

efficient and secure platform for global trade §1

Carbon-credit

market

Veridium Labs and IBM are working together to improve the

operations of carbon-credit markets using Blockchain technology §1

Long Island

Iced Tea

Long Island Iced Tea announced that it is moving from being in

the beverage business to Blockchain mining and changed its name

to Long Island Blockchain

§1

Delta

Technology

Holdings

The stock price of Delta Technology Holdings (a chemical

manufacturer in China) went up 200% on announcement that it

will be involved in Blockchain

§1

Bitcoin The first application of Blockchain §1

Ethereum,

Hyperledger

Fabric, and

Ripple

Popular Blockchain platforms §2

Populous Trade finance platform that uses smart contracts for immediate and

automatic payments when certain contractual conditions are met §2

Oracalize,

Signatura,

ChainLink

Secure information providers (“oracles”) §2.1.2

Mangos Walmart ran a pilot project of tracking mangos from Mexico to

Walmart shelves §4.2

CryptoKitties The number of pending transactions on the Etherium network

increased six fold in weeks following the launch of CryptoKitties §5

Trade finance

FnConn, a subsidiary of FoxConn, announced in 2017 a launch of a

Blockchain-based platform for providing working capital to firms in

FoxConn’s supply chain

§B.3